R. Prasad
Ram Prasad is with the Indian Institute of Forest Management, Bhopal, India.
Case studies suggest that state NWFP monopolies may have disadvantages for the collectors and for the forests.
The Indian Forest Policy of 1988 (MoEF, 1988) and the subsequent government resolution on participatory forest management (MoEF, 1990) emphasize the need for people's participation in natural forest management. The policy document asserts that local communities should be motivated to identify themselves with the development and protection of the forests from which they derive benefits. Thus, the policy envisages a process of joint management of forests by the state governments (which have nominal responsibility) and the local people, which would share both the responsibility for managing the resource and the benefits that accrue from this management.
Under joint forest management (JFM), village communities are entrusted with the protection and management of nearby forests. The areas concerned are usually degraded or even deforested areas. However, in Andhra Pradesh and Madhya Pradesh all village fringe forests can come under JFM. The communities are required to organize forest protection committees, village forest committees, village forest conservation and development societies, etc. Each of these bodies has an executive committee that manages its day-to-day affairs.
Non-wood forest products (NWFPs) have a key role in JFM efforts. With the increasing awareness of their economic potential and growing concerns for the sustainability of the resources and the distribution of the benefits derived from them, various state governments have taken over control of a number of NWFPs. This article, by looking at case studies of some selected NWFPs, questions whether this process has met its objectives - ensuring fair wages to the collectors, enhancing forest protection and increasing state revenues, for example - and examines its impact on joint forest management.
IMPORTANCE OF NWFPs IN JOINT FOREST MANAGEMENT
Non-wood forest products are important to JFM efforts for a number of reasons. First, NWFPs are integral to the lifestyle of forest-dependent communities. They fulfil basic requirements, provide gainful employment during lean periods and supplement incomes from agriculture and wage labour. Medicinal plants have an important role in rural health (Prasad and Bhatnagar, 1991). In parts of West Bengal, communities derive as much as 17 percent of their annual household income from NWFP collection and sale (Malhotra et al., 1991). According to J.Y. Campbell (1988, cited in Tewari and Campbell, 1995), small-scale forest-based enterprises, many of which rely on NWFPs, provide up to 50 percent of the income for about 25 percent of India's rural labour force.
Second, NWFPs have a decided advantage over timber in terms of the time needed to achieve significant volumes of commercially valuable production. Timber production is a long-term endeavour, and in many areas timber harvesting may not be ecologically desirable. Moreover, many NWFPs become available even in the earliest stages of rehabilitation of degraded forest areas.
Third, at the national level over 50 percent of forest revenue and about 70 percent of forest export revenue comes from NWFPs, mostly from unprocessed and raw forms (Tewari and Campbell 1997; Prasad, Shukla and Bhatnagar, 1996).
Thus NWFP management has clear ecological, social and economic benefits. Managing forests for multiple products including NWFPs and adding value to them at the local level are two of the most pressing challenges facing the JFM programme. In attempts to optimize the production of multiple products to meet the objectives of the various stakeholders, due attention should be paid to the potential for sustainable production of NWFPs in forest management efforts, including JFM arrangements. The true spirit of JFM gets translated only when forests are also managed to meet the people's needs.
Tribal dependence on NWFPs in Orissa Precise estimates of tribal dependence on NWFPs for their own consumption or sale are not available. However, a study conducted by the Indian Institute of Forest Management in 1996 (MoEF, 1998) gives a fair idea about the pattern of NWFP collection and the contribution of these products to the economy of three tribes (Kondhs, Mundas and Saoras) in Orissa. The study was conducted in 301 randomly selected households spread over six districts of Orissa (Boudh, Pholbani, Keonjhar, Mayturbhanj, Sundargarh and Gajapati). It was observed that an average tribal family drew about one-half of its annual income from forests, 18 percent from agriculture, 13 percent from cattle and 18 percent from other employment. Approximately one-third of the products gathered from forests were traded. |
THE MOVE TOWARDS STATE CONTROL OF NWFPs
Traditionally, the collection of NWFPs has been of low intensity and generally sustainable. However, as the economic potential of NWFPs has become apparent, the intensity of collection has increased and more significant infrastructures for trade and processing have developed. This has raised concerns for the sustainability of the resources and the distribution of the benefits derived from them. In reaction to these concerns, a number of state governments have taken over the control of a number of NWFPs. The state regulations bringing certain NWFPs under monopoly trade are summarized in Table 1. Some of the explicit objectives for state monopoly of NWFP trade are:
· to prevent unscrupulous intermediaries and their agents from exploiting NWFP collectors:
· to ensure fair wages to collectors:
· to enhance revenue for the state:
· to ensure quality;
· to maximize the collection of produce (Prasad et al., 1996).
In most cases, trading is controlled through state-owned institutions such as state forest development corporations, federations, cooperatives and tribal societies. In Orissa, however, where the Forest Produce (Control and Trade) Act of 1981 provides the scope for a state monopoly on certain selected forest products, the state also has the option to give monopoly leases for collection and trade of forest products. In fact, the state has granted monopoly rights for 29 NWFP items to a private company, Utkal Forest Products Ltd (Prasad and Saxena, 1996; Agragamee, 1997; MoEF, 1998). Under this agreement, the local people who collect NWFPs are required to sell their collected materials to the company's agents at preset prices that are lower than those they could have obtained by selling directly to processors. It is noteworthy that some of the 29 items yield very insignificant amounts of revenue yet have nevertheless been taken under the state monopoly.
Collection and trade of tendu leaves under state monopoly
The first NWFP brought under state control was tendu leaves (Diospyros melanoxylon), used to wrap traditional cigarettes (bidi). This tree species is found in abundance in tropical deciduous forests, on wastelands to some extent and even on private holdings. Tendu collection was monopolized by Madhya Pradesh in 1964 (see Table 2), followed by Maharashtra (1969), Andhra Pradesh (1971), Bihar (1973), Gujarat (1979) and Orissa (1981) (see Table 3). The monopolization of tendu was rapidly followed by similar procedures for other economically important NWFPs, including sal seed (Shorea robusta), gums and myrobalan (Terminalia chebula and Terminalia bellerica).
Before Madhya Pradesh adopted a cooperative structure for tendu leaf trade in 1988, the collection of leaves as per official records ranged from 6 to 7 million standard bags (Table 2). This was reduced to around 4 million standard bags per year after 1989. The reduction did not result from a lack of resources, but rather from the rejection of leaves that would previously have been collected but were not of high enough quality for the cooperatives (Prasad, Shukla and Bhatnagar. 1996). However, local manufacturers of bidi cigarettes have been known to buy additional tendu leaves directly from collectors.
In Madhya Pradesh, collectors share in profits through a bonus plan at the end of each season. In Orissa, which is also rich in NWFPs, the collectors get only wages for collection; the bulk of the profit goes to the Forest Development Corporation, which has been given monopoly rights by the state government (Agragamee, 1997). As in Madhya Pradesh, collection of tendu leaves is being limited by a desire to collect only the best produce.
TABLE 1. State trading regulations promulgated by state governments
State |
Regulations |
Implications |
Andhra Pradesh |
Andhra Pradesh Minor Forest Produce (Regulation of Trade) Act, 1971 |
Trade in NWFPs is declared state monopoly whether ownership is with government or not |
Bihar |
Bihar Kendu Leaves (Control of Trade) Act, 1973 |
Bihar State Forest Development Corporation operates as state government agent for collection and marketing of kendu leaves, sal seed, mahua (Madhuca latifolia) and harra |
Gujarat |
Gujarat Minor Forest Produce (Regulation of Trade) Act, 1979 |
Minor forest products identified include timru leaves (tendu leaves), mahua flowers, fruits, seeds and gum |
Himachal Pradesh |
Himachal Pradesh Resin and Resin Produce (Regulation of Trade) Act, 1981 |
Resin, bamboo and Acacia catechu (khair) collection through Himachal Pradesh Forest Development Corporation Ltd |
Madhya Pradesh |
Madhya Pradesh Vanopaj (Vyapar Viniyam) Adhiniyam, 1969 |
Items under monopoly include tendu leaves, sal seed, harra and gums; Madhya Pradesh Minor Forest Produce (Trade and Development) Federation acts as agent of state government |
Rajasthan |
Rajasthan Tendu Leaves Act, 1974 |
Rajasthan Tribal Area Development Federation collects and markets NWFPs |
Orissa |
Orissa Forest Produce (Control of Trade) Act, 1981 |
Collection and sale of NWFPs are monopolized by Forest Department and leased to Tribal Development Cooperative Society which in turn delegates to an individual; collection and trade of leaves are handled by Forest Corporation |
Source: MoEF, 1998.
TABLE 2. Phases in collection of tendu leaves in Madhya Pradesh
Phase |
Total period |
Collection per year |
Growth rate |
1965-1980 |
15 |
2-3 |
+1.0 |
1981-1988 |
8 |
6-7 |
+5.93 |
1989-1996 |
8 |
4 |
-1.87 |
Source: Prasad, Shukla and Bhatnagar, 1996.
TABLE 3. Trends in collection of some monopolized NWFPs in Orissa
Product |
Collection |
Increase or decrease |
|
Before state monopoly |
After state monopoly |
||
Tendu leaves |
36 000 (1967-1973) |
35200 (1979-1985) |
-2.02 |
Sal seeds |
200 000 (1977) |
60000 (1987) |
-70 |
Lac |
32 000 (1961-1970) |
16000 (1981-1986) |
-50 |
Source: Agragamee, 1997.
Monopoly of broomstick grass and other NWFPs in Orissa
Broomstick grass grows wild in most hilly tracts of the Raygada district of Orissa. Tribal women, through JFM forest protection committees, have protected this grass from grazing and fire and have obtained income by selling it. However, since the trade in broomstick grass has come under state control its collection and sale have been much reduced. While the women get 1.5 to 3 rupees (US$0.03 to $0.06) per kilogram of broomstick grass, the company holding the monopoly (Utkal Forest Products Ltd) is making profits of as much as 600 percent (Prasad and Saxena, 1996; Agragamee, 1997). Reduced collection has also been observed for T. chebula, gums and mahua (Madhuca latifolia) flowers since these were taken under state monopoly. However, collection of Buchananea lanzan and Chlorophytum tubersum (safed musli) has increased, perhaps to the point of unsustainability, in response to high commercial demand (Bhatnagar and Bhavsar, 1988; Prasad and Bhatnagar, 1990, 1991).
DOES THE STATE MONOPOLY MEET ITS OBJECTIVES?
While the objectives of creating state monopolies are laudable, a comparison of the declared objectives and the actual situation (Table 4) suggests that on the whole the results are not favourable. Although state forest revenues have increased, the forest-dependent communities do not appear to be reaping benefits in terms of wages, socio-economic conditions or gender equity, and the cost to end users has continued to increase. Intermediaries have not been eliminated, but have been replaced by agents of the monopoly leaseholders. Moreover, forest degradation has not been halted, and destructive harvesting has been observed in some cases where the prospect of short-term profit has obscured care for long-term sustainability.
TABLE 4. Declared objectives of NWFP trade monopoly and the field situation
Stated objectives |
Actual situation |
Welfare of forest-dependent communities | |
Ensuring access to forests (implied) |
Restricted by agents and subagents of government, e.g. in Orissa. (Agragamee, 1997) |
Ensuring fair wages through prompt |
In Orissa, bulk profits are being apportioned by and just payments intermediaries/state government; in Madhya Pradesh, payments are not only delayed, but are inadequate because of the managed collection of predetermined quantity (see Table 2) |
Elimination of intermediaries |
Intermediaries are agents and subagents of monopoly leaseholders, e.g. in Orissa (Agragamee, 1997) |
Preventing exploitation of NWFP collectors |
Where government alone does the marketing, it is inefficient; where marketing is left to private trade, it is exploitative (Prasad and Saxena, 1996) |
Ensuring better socio-economic conditions |
Perceptible improvement in economic conditions is not in sight |
Maximizing collection to ensure more wages |
Collection is regulated and thus the full advantage of the produce is not available to the NWFP gatherers, as illustrated by declining collection in Orissa and Madhya Pradesh |
Maintenance of benefit sharing and gender equity |
The National Commission on Women reported very low payments to women, partly because of ignorance and partly because of women's fear of being denied collection access to forests (Prasad and Saxena, 1996) |
Sustainable forest management | |
Sustainable harvesting |
Agents and subagents of monopoly leaseholders are interested in enhanced return and are unmindful of the long-term impact of destructive harvesting (Emblica officinalis, Buchanania lanzan, Diospyros melanoxylon. Madhuca spp.) |
Forest protection |
Collection of sal seed, mahua (Madhuca latifolia), etc. is associated with extensive forest fire to clear the ground of leaf litter and to ensure clear visibility of the produce on the ground |
Natural regeneration |
Regeneration is very poor because of destructive harvesting, grazing and fire |
Forest productivity |
Forest degradation continues |
Forest revenue to state |
Forest revenue to state has increased tremendously |
Protection of end users' interests |
End users continues to pay more because the market is controlled by others |
IMPACT OF THE MONOPOLY OF NWFPs ON JOINT FOREST MANAGEMENT
In many states the membership of JFM committees and primary forest produce collectors (PFPCs) societies are not the same. While membership in forest protection committees (FPCs) and village forest committees (VFCs) is open to all families of the village, PFPCs are made up of collectors only. FPCs and VFCs are entrusted with the conservation and development of forests and NWFPs, but no such responsibilities are assigned to the NWFP collectors. Thus, while the PFPCs get the bonuses and other monetary benefits accruing from the sale of NWFPs under monopoly, they are not held responsible for management of the resource. On the other hand, those who are tasked with protection of the resource do not share in the benefits of its exploitation. The two types of organizations therefore need to be integrated so that the interests of members conserving and developing the forest resource and those of NWFP collectors do not clash. This could be done by inclusion of members of JFM committees in the PFPCs. Alternatively, part of the profit from NWFPs could also be given to JFM committee members who are not part of the PFPCs.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
It appears that the objectives of bringing NWFPs under state monopoly - to reduce exploitation of tribal people and other forest-dependent communities and to promote sustainable management of NWFPs - are not being realized. State control over the trade of NWFPs has often resulted in compounded problems of restricted access to resources and non-remunerative returns to the collectors. NWFPs are one of the keys to successful joint forest management, but if local people who are engaged in the arduous task of collecting NWFPs are not able to get fair wages even when the trade is handled by government-appointed agencies, JFM may not be a viable tool in the achievement of sustainable forest management.
Bibliography
Agragamee. 1997. Mandibishi Mahila Mandal, hill brooms and TDCC - a case of a government against its people. In S.R. Hiremath, ed. Forest lands and forest produce: as if people mattered. Dharwad, Karnataka, India, National Committee for Protection of Natural Resources (NCPR).
Bhatnagar. P. & Bhavsar, K.N. 1988. Economic potential of Buchanania lanzan in Madhya Pradesh. Vaniki-Sandesh (SFRI), 12(4): 16-20.
Malhotra, K.C., Deb, D., Dutta, M., Vasula, T.S., Yadav, G. & Adhikari, M. 1991. Role of non-timber forest produce in village economy. A household survey in Jamboni Range, Midnapore, West Bengal. Calcutta, India, Indian Institute of Biosocial Research and Development (IBRAD).
Ministry of Environment and Forests (MoEF) of India. 1988. National Forest Policy (1988). Resolution No. 3-1/86-FP. New Delhi, India, Department of Environment, Forests and Wildlife.
MoEF. 1990. Joint Forest Management Resolution. Resolution No. 6-21/89-FP. New Delhi, India, Department of Environment, Forests and Wildlife.
MoEF. 1998. Report of the Expert Committee on Confering Ownership Rights of MFPs on Panchayats. New Delhi, India, Government of India, (unpublished)
Prasad, R. & Bhatnagar, P. 1990. Socio-economic potential of minor forest produce in Madhya Pradesh. SFRI Bulletin No. 26. Jabalpur, India, State Forest Research Institute.
Prasad, R. & Bhatnagar, P. 1991. Wild edible products in the forests of Madhya Pradesh. Journal of Tropical Forestry, 7(3): 210-218.
Prasad, R. & Saxena, N.C. 1996. Role of the state in NTFP marketing exchanges. Bangalore, India, Actionaid.
Prasad, R., Shukla, P.K. & Bhatnagar, P. 1996. Leaves from the forest: a case study of tendu leaves in Madhya Pradesh. Jabalpur, Madhya Pradesh, India, Centre for Environment and Sustainable Development.
Tewari, D.D. & Campbell, J.Y. 1995. Developing and sustaining non-timber forest products: some policy issues and concerns with special reference to India. Journal of Sustainable Forestry, 3(1): 53-77.
Tewari, D.D. & Campbell, J.Y. 1997. Economics of non-timber forest products. In J.M. Kerr, D.K. Marothia, K. Singh, C. Ramaswamy & W.B. Bentley, eds. Natural resource economics - theory and application. New Delhi, India, Oxford and IBH.