Previous PageTable Of ContentsNext Page

Forestland resource ownership and valuation

Ownership

The issues covered in this section deal essentially with ownership of forestland and the determination of its value. Issues related to "economic rents" inherent in forestlands are reviewed, as are issues related to their realisation and distribution. Immediately below (Table 3.1.1) are presented harvest statistics for Latvia.

Table 3.1.1: Latvian annual harvest statistics (by ownership), (‘000 m3)

 

Year

 

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997IX

1998

                 

State forests

3575

3,059

3,797

4,729

5,298

4,483

4,870

 

Private forests

--

--

--

--

--

1,471

3,361

 

Agriculture enterprises

782

881

882

901

1,333

606

479

 

Other

35

75

78

100

256

205

213

 

Subtotal (=total cut)

4,392

4,015

4,757

5,730

6,887

6,765

8,923

 
                 

by final cut

3,083

     

3,481

4,126

5,490

 

(of which) clear cuts

3,077

     

3,370

3,954

   
                 

by intermediate cuts

1,133

     

2,848

2,253

3,016

 

(of which) cleaning

5

     

12

13

   

Thinning

594

     

1,210

925

 

Sanitary

521

     

1,615

1,299

1,547

 

Conversion

13

     

11

16

   

Windfall & other

176

     

558

386

417

 

1/ Source: CBSa, CBSf

Valuation should be of no less concern to state owners or forestland resources than it is to private owners. Neither is interested in foregoing any of its potential revenue. Each is interested in maintaining its various benefits at their highest level – including that of timer sales.

Issues relating to timber tenures are often amongst the more contentious of those which state forest authorities must deal with. Other ownership issues include the exclusivity of user access, the enforceability of the owner/ user’s claim, as well as its divisibility and transferability. Aspects of these issues are familiar to Latvia – having been taken into consideration in the post-independence redistribution of land.

The state’s sovereign right permits it to retain exclusive title to all potential benefits of state forest land resources – though legitimate access is allocated to other users through a variety of short-term and long-term mechanism.

In Latvia’s case, the state also reserves the right to prescribe post-harvest reforestation on private forestlands. This means that, in respect of forestlands, the state assume both - a public sector "governance" role, and a private sector "entrepreneur’s" role. It is the potential conflict surrounding these divergent interests that constitutes one of the major issues for the ROL/FAO project.

A high level and public debate in Latvia currently suggest that there exist a potential perception of conflict between the state in its role as a forest landowner and in its role as an enforcer of forest practices and legislation. Suggestions also include consideration of assigning these responsibilities to separate state structures.

Instigating effective mechanisms to ensure responsibility, accountability and transparency is essential for competitive and equitable forest sector development. In their presence, a wider range of governance and management options may succeed than in their absence.

In well developed mature forestry constituencies a combined ownership / enforcer role may be far less problematic – if at all. This is less the case where there exists a legacy of a command economy, and an historically lower level of responsible, accountable, and transparent governance and management. Latvia’s situation precludes the continued assumption of the dual management-enforcer role in the short term at least – though, in the long term other options exist.

The level of funding on non-wage expenditures on state owned/managed forests is far below what is required for their efficient management and exploitation. Table 3.1.2 gives funding levels for state forest authorities for this decade.

Table 3.1.2: State forest budgets (‘000,000 LVL)

 

Year

 

1991 1/

1992 2/

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Base funding

54

430

3.1

3.4

9

"Special Budget"

     

3.3

15

13.6

14

22.5

total

54

430

3.1

6.7

24

13.6

14

22.5

Source: Finance & Statistics Department, LSFS; 1/ old roubles, 2/ new roubles,

It is widely accepted that current state budget allotments to the Forest Service and Forest Department have been inadequate for a number of years. Ultimately, inadequate funding compromises efforts to maximise the productivity of forestlands. The state responds to criticism on this point by reference to the inadequacy of its revenues from forestry activities. Private forest interests, thereupon, point out that the state is indifferent to industry’s declared inability to fund similar activities – at the state’s insistence that this is part of tenure arrangements.

 

Valuation

Independent of its ownership, forestland should be viewed as a capital asset – yielding many benefits quantifiable in many ways. As stated earlier, it is the extent to which these benefits are tangible and quantifiable that often determines whether or not they are ultimately considered in forestland valuation calculations. Timber values are easy to quantify. However, many benefits deriving from forestland are not easy to even identify, let alone quantify - for example, that of soil and water conservation. At least one glaring consequence of the above is the absence in most nation’s System of National Accounts of figures to account for the depreciation (and appreciation) of forestland.

For a number of reasons the natural capital that is the forestland base of Latvia is not maximising its yield. Operation and budgetary issues feature prominently in the cause. However, issues related to crop establishment, thinning and rotation age at harvesting also warrant review. Decisions on these crop management parameters must be based upon their impact upon harvest yields and values – a strategy that is still to be more effectively integrated into forest management in Latvia.

The actual practice of forest management in Latvia can be improved by adopting more appropriate practices – especially in key areas such as:

stand growth and yield modelling

timber allocation and stumpage determination mechanisms

harvest development planning

forest and forestry information management systems.

A clearer understanding of the relationship between stand characteristics and end product quality and value must guide forest management and harvesting development decisions. There is limited scope for reliance on intuition and local traditions in attempting to optimise the magnitude and distribution of benefits from Latvia’s forestlands. Historical forest management practices must be replaced with approaches better matched to a market economy. Latvia will otherwise be less than optimally placed to successfully compete in these markets.

Forest management at executive, management and operations levels in Latvia – both public and private sector - will be sub-optimal until such time as resource valuation more directly informs decision making at each of these levels.

Comprehensive valuation methodologies must include estimates on physical and economic accessibility, potential log size distribution and quality, and potential end-product conversion rates and sales values. Valuations can be based upon current growing stock but must includes projections based upon employing updated stand establishment and management practices.

Valuation calculations would be applied at district and regional levels – and aggregated to produce national level figures. All such information would be freely available to all stakeholders.

 

Stumpage Calculation and Collection

Perhaps the most striking and unsupportable artefact of the former command economy is the insistence upon incorporating stumpage rates directly into higher level governance instruments.

The lengthy process of legislative change invariably eliminates any ability to adjust stumpage rates in a timely manner in response to changing market circumstances. The consequences of this include:

in cases where end product selling prices fall

i) above normal state revenues at the cost of producers / sellers

ii) below "normal" profits for producers / sellers

in cases where end product selling prices increase

below normal state revenues in favour of producers / sellers

above "normal" profits for producers/sellers

Furthermore, in Latvia stumpage rates are currently established largely independent of any link to rational pricing principles or market concepts. From an economic perspective, this practice can not be rationally justified.

Ordinarily, the ministry responsible for forests, as managers of the state’s (public’s) forests, authorises the sale of forest stands to timber developers, (operators, loggers, contractors, etc.) - for a fee. The fee is frequently related to – and often exactly equal to – an "economic surplus" or "residual value" accruing to the conversion process (tree to log). This is generally determined by the following formula:

 

Stumpage = Selling Price - [Operating Costs + Normal Profit ]

 

Fees for the use or harvest of any forest product - wood or non-wood - can be calculated on similar principles.

Stumpage collections usually become part of general revenues and are managed for the state by their financial ministries. They are generally not "earmarked" for specific forestry purposes, but disbursed through normal state budget processes.

Social, political and economic priorities will determine the ultimate redistribution of any government revenue collections. State budgets will ordinarily determine the amount that eventually returns to the Ministry of Forests. This funding is then available to manage the state’s forests.

Redistribution of revenues collected from an "economic surplus" (stumpage or other user fees) can take many forms. Fundamentally, an efficient and equitable approach to collecting and redistributing forestry fees recognises that many stakeholders may have legitimate claims to a share of the benefits of the republic’s forest resources – and should therefore be funded out of collected surpluses.

Unless a rational approach is used that provides "normal" returns to legitimate claimants (state, owners, labour, etc.) markets will become distorted, efficiency will be compromised, and economic rent distributions will remain inequitable.

Workers should receive fair wages. Licensees should receive a fair ("normal") profit on their invested capital - usually measured as the profit realised by "an operator of average efficiency". A fair profit or "normal profit" recognises the operator’s realistic costs and an amount that essentially represents the payment to his own entrepreneurial inputs for assuming the risks involved. Operators that are more efficient will realise slightly better returns - less efficient operators have lower profits and in some cases may succumb to business failure.

 

Previous PageTop Of PageNext Page