The implications of the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture for developing countries



Chapter 3: Implications of the Agreement on Agriculture for agricultural policies and trade in developing countries

 

What this chapter is about

The purpose of this chapter is to look in detail at the Agricultural Agreement and the implications it has for agricultural and trade policies in developing countries. The chapter will examine the differential treatment that developing countries receive under the agreement, it will provide a guide to using and interpreting the agreement, and will examine to what extent full compliance with the agreement will affect existing agricultural policies in the developing country context.

Following the introduction, this chapter is divided according to the main sections of the Agreement, that is, market access, domestic support commitments and export subsidies. Each of these sections acts as a guide to the relevant Articles and Annexes of the Agreement, examining how the various paragraphs and clauses should be interpreted, and highlighting areas where developing country commitments are different from those of developed countries. Each section will look at the policy implications of compliance, both during the implementation period, and beyond. The chapter will pay particular attention to some of the practical details involved in complying with the Agreement, such as, for example, how to calculate an AMS, or how to establish the permitted level of additional tariff under the Special Safeguards provisions.

Aims of this chapter

  • Summarise the special and differential treatment accorded to developing and least developed countries.
  • Provide a guide to the relevant Articles and Annexes of the Agreement.
  • Examine how the various paragraphs and clauses should be interpreted.
  • Highlight areas where developing country commitments are different from those of developed countries.
  • Consider the policy implications of compliance, both during the implementation period, and beyond.
  • Study the practical details involved in complying with the Agreement, such as, for example, how to calculate an AMS.
  • What you will learn

  • How the process of tariffication is undertaken: how to convert NTBs into tariff equivalents.
  • About bound rates and base rates of duty and their significance.
  • What are tariff rate quotas and how they are used.
  • About special treatment and special safeguard provisions.
  • The significance of 'dirty tariffication' and other implementation issues.
  • What 'green box' policies consist of and the implications of such a classification.
  • About other exemptions from the AMS.
  • How to calculate the AMS.
  • The implications of implementing the domestic support commitments.
  • About the provisions regarding export subsidies and their significance for developing countries.
  • 3.1 The general implications of the Agreement for developing countries: Special and differential treatment

    The Agreement is likely to affect agricultural policies in developing countries in a number of ways. In the first instance, some areas of domestic agricultural policy and trade policy in developing countries will need to be modified in order to comply with the Agreement's provisions. It is these direct implications that will receive emphasis in the current chapter. The Agreement will also influence the agricultural policies of developing countries in a less direct way. This will occur, firstly, as a result of the Uruguay Round's impact upon the policies of the 'rest of the world', particularly, those of the developed countries; and, secondly, as a result of the impact on world markets and world prices, that reforms in the policies of the rest of the world will have. In the long term, changes in world markets and prices will provide new opportunities, as well as certain costs, that agricultural policies of developing countries will have to respond to. Changes in world market prices will, for, example influence the profitability of different commodity sectors, which may in turn, affect public sector investment policies. Analysis of these wider implications is, however, left until a later chapter, and for now we shall concentrate on the more immediate effects of the Agreement.

    Before looking in more detail at the Provisions of the Agreement on Agriculture, it is useful to review the ways in which the provisions differ for developing and least developed countries compared to developed countries. This 'Special and Differential Treatment' as far as the Agricultural Agreement is concerned is introduced in Article 15. Thus:

    • The Agreement has maintained the principles of Special and Differential Treatment for developing countries, introduced in earlier rounds of the GATT.
    • It maintains and reinforces the distinction between Developing Countries and Least-Developed Countries, that was initially made during the Tokyo Round.

    It is now commonly accepted that disciplines of the Uruguay Round Agreement, affecting as they do many previously unregulated areas, have introduced a vast array of obligations that did not previously exist. At the same time, it has been recognised that the ability to meet these new obligations varies considerably from one country to another, and that while full participation in the new commitments may be appropriate for the more developed countries, it may not be so for less developed countries.

    As a result, many of the new agreements, including the Agreement on Agriculture, contain within them provisions that differentiate the rights and obligations of member countries, according to whether they are developed, developing or least-developed. In general, developed countries are expected to participate fully in the new disciplines, while for developing countries the commitments are less demanding.

    • The expected concessions tend to be smaller: reduction commitments are typically two-thirds of those for developed countries, and implementation periods longer: 10 years as opposed to 6.
    • Least-developed countries, on the other hand, enjoy the same benefits as other developing countries, but are also able to claim a number of additional exemptions.

    The UN definition of a least-developed country is the one used by the WTO. There are, nevertheless, some problems with this definition, since it is not designed to measure trade competitiveness and excludes some low-income countries that probably should be included. Greater ambiguity exists over the definition of a developing country, and this could possibly be a source of contention in future trade disputes. The principle followed in the GATT/WTO is that of self designation. In agreeing the schedules countries opted to be included in one category or another. However, the ultimate designation was potentially the subject of negotiation, and therefore of influence, by other member states.

    The sections which follow will look in detail at the commitments of developing and least-developed countries with regards to the relevant provisions on market access, domestic support and export subsidies.

    3.2 Market access provisions

    As discussed in Chapter 2, the main elements of the Agreement's provisions on market access relate to tariffication, tariff reduction, minimum access commitments and a number of exemptions. The associated provisions and commitments are documented in the text of the Agricultural Agreement itself, in the Modalities and in the relevant Country Schedules. The first and the last of these are legally binding documents, whilst the Modalities were only binding up until the point at which the Country Schedules were submitted to the WTO.

    In the Agreement itself the main article on 'Market Access' (Article 4) is short, and is limited to just two paragraphs. The first of these is concerned with tariffs and merely refers to the Country Schedules in which the legally binding commitments on tariff bindings, and reductions, as well as minimum access concessions, are to be found. The implication of this is as follows:

    • The exact value of the tariff commitments in the Schedules should have been established by each country in accordance with rules laid out in the Modalities, and that even if the Modalities were not strictly followed, the resulting Country Schedules are still legally binding.

    The second paragraph is also very short, and is concerned with NTBs. It requires that:

    • Member states restrict their use of import barriers to the tariffs specified in their Country Schedules, forbidding countries from using non-tariff barriers to trade, except for those exempted according to the provisions of Article 5 and Annex 5.

    Article 5 is concerned with the Special Safeguard Provisions and Annex 5 with Special Treatment. The former allow countries, under particular circumstances, to raise tariffs above the level stipulated in their Schedules, while the latter permits a country to retain NTBs for certain sensitive products. Details of these exemptions are discussed below. The prohibited NTBs are provided in a footnote to Article 4, Paragraph 2 and are as follows:

    • quantitative import restrictions;

    • variable import levies;

    • minimum import prices;

    • discretionary import licensing;

    • non-tariff measures maintained through state-trading enterprises;

    • voluntary export restraints;

    • similar border measures other than ordinary customs duties.

    3.2.1 Tariffication and tariff reduction

    We will now look at the essentials of the market access provisions in more detail. Thus we focus on the process of tariffication, and the concept of the base rate of duty. The way in which tariffication has been carried out has been criticised by some commentators, as have the implications of the manner in which the base rates of duty have been calculated.

    The base rate of duty for tariffied commodities

    The obligation to convert NTBs into tariff equivalents applies to all member states, including developing and least-developed countries. This tariffication process involves converting the average rate of protection provided by NTBs during the base period (1986-88), into a tariff equivalent, and thereby establishing a base rate of duty for each product covered by the agreement.

    Box 3.1: The mechanism for converting NTBs to tariff equivalents

    The base rate of duty for products which are previously subject to a tariff

    For previously bound tariffs, that is those with an upper ceiling, the base rate of duty is determined by this previous bound level. For unbound tariffs the situation is slightly different. Thus:

    • Where the product was already subject to a bound tariff during the base period, that bound rate, or the bound rate prevailing on 1 September 1986, (whichever is higher), acts as the base rate of duty.
    • Developing countries which had unbound ordinary customs duties had the option of offering ceiling bindings on these products. A significant proportion followed this course of action.

    All signatories should have completed this process before submitting their Schedules to the GATT, with the resulting base rate of duty for each commodity listed in the relevant column of the Country Schedules.

    The bound rate of duty

    The bound rate of duty is listed in the Country Schedules in an adjacent column to the base rate of duty. This the level at which the final tariff for a particular product should be bound. It is, in other words, the maximum tariff that may be applied from the point of time at which it comes into effect.

    The bound rate of duty for each product is the result of a reduction in the base rate of duty. It is established by:

    • Reducing the base rate of duty for each product by a minimum of 10 percent in the case of developing countries and by 15 percent in the case of developed countries.
    • Reducing the unweighted average of all base rates by at least 24 percent and 36 percent in the case of developing and developed countries respectively.
    There are two cases where members are not required to reduce their base rates of duty:

    • Least-developed countries are not required to cut the base rate of duty, hence, their bound rates need not be less than the base rate for any given product.
    • For those developing countries that offered ceiling bindings, there is no obligation to reduce them.
    Again, it should be noted that the bound rate of duty stipulated in the Country Schedule is legally binding, however it might have been calculated in practice.

    The implementation period

    The year in which the bound tariff becomes effective, again, depends upon the commitments made in the Country Schedule.

    • For developing countries committed to tariff reductions, the minimum requirement is that the implementation period is 1995-2004, implying that the bound rate should be implemented by the year 2004, in accordance with the Agreement's provision that extends the usual 6 year implementation period, for developed countries, to ten years in the case of developing countries.
    • For least-developed countries the bound rate should have become effective at the beginning of the implementation period, i.e. in 1995. Once in effect the bound rates of duty should not be exceeded, except where the Special Safeguard Provisions apply.

    The sequencing of the reduction commitments as applied to tariffs should be implemented, according to Paragraph 7 of the Modalities, in equal annual installments. At the same time, it is worth noting that many developing country Schedules do not include annual commitments, but simply refer to reduction commitments being implemented over the 1995-2004 implementation period. It is worth remembering here that it is the Country Schedules rather than the modalities which are the legally binding documents.

    3.2.2 Minimum Access Commitments

    Details on how the level of minimum access commitments should be established were given in the Modalities rather than the Agreement itself. Since, as mentioned above, the modalities ceased to have any validity once the Country Schedules were accepted, the legally binding minimum access levels are now determined entirely by the extent to which the provisions of the Modalities were translated into commitments in the Country Schedules.

    Where there were no significant imports, the Modalities obliged countries to provide minimum access opportunities, that would allow exporters of tariffied products (products that have undergone tariffication) to supply at least 3 percent of domestic consumption at the beginning of the implementation period, rising to 5 percent at the end of the implementation period, i.e. by 2004.

    This implies that a proportion of the imports of a commodity which had previously been subject to NTBs would be allowed into the importing country at a reduced tariff rate. This quantity would be a minimum of 3 percent of the value of domestic consumption in 1995 at the beginning of the implementation, rising to 5 percent by 2004. Hence:

    • Minimum access opportunities shall be implemented on the basis of a tariff quota at a low or nominal rate according to the Most Favoured Nation (MFN) principle.
    • The volume of domestic consumption, to which minimum access volumes are related, is defined as the volume consumed during the base period 1986-88.

    Compliance with minimum access provisions has generally involved the specification in the Country Schedule of an initial tariff rate quota (TRQ) and a final TRQ for each tariffied product involved.

    • A TRQ is the quota of imports that is permitted to enter the country at below the normal tariff rate.

    These arrangements are laid out in the Country Schedules as follows:

    • The column entitled initial quota is divided into two columns, the first column containing the size of the quota in metric tonnes, and the second column containing the tariff rate applied to within-quota imports.
    • Another column, entitled final quota, is divided in a similar way and reflects any changes in the initial quota (e.g. increased quota size, or reduced tariff) that are required in order to raise access opportunities from the initial minimum level (3 percent of domestic consumption) to the final minimum level (5 percent) at the end of implementation period.

    In fact, the provisions on minimum access are somewhat ambiguous and have been interpreted in a variety of different ways:

    • According to the Modalities, minimum access quotas are supposed to be available according to the MFN principle; that is, an importing country is not in theory permitted to discriminate between different exporters in the application of its minimum access TRQs.

    However, the intention of the Agreement was also to protect the exports of existing exporters; i.e. to safeguard current access.

    • Current access to developed country markets, by developing country exporters has frequently been provided under bilateral trade arrangements in which specified countries are offered market access at preferential tariff rates.

    These arrangements are protected by the Agreement. They are different from the minimum access quotas, in the sense that they are not offered on an MFN basis. Nevertheless, they have been included in the quotas specified in the Country Schedules, with appropriate notes on which exporters enjoy the quotas.

    These arrangements are different to the minimum access provisions. Where, previously, there was no market access, the minimum provisions have been agreed, but this is separate from any arrangements regarding current access. The two are not cumulative. It is possible, however, that minimum access quotas could be used to maintain existing bi-lateral agreements, rather than to offer concessionary tariffs on a MFN basis.

    There is also uncertainty surrounding the procedures for allocating minimum access (rather than current access ) quotas:

    • The recipients of licenses to import at in-quota tariff rates will benefit from economic rents, hence countries have an interest in allocating these licenses to domestic traders rather than to foreign traders, although this may not be entirely consistent with MFN principles.

    The auction of such quotas may offer a more equitable solution; but, the price that is paid for auctioned licenses imposes an additional levy on trade, and could be construed as being in breach of WTO/GATT rules. These are issues that WTO still has to resolve.

    3.2.3 Special treatment

    The paragraphs regarding Special Treatment are found in Annex 5 of the Agreement. As has already been mentioned, circumstances do exist under the Agreement in which countries have been permitted to exempt certain products from tariffication commitments: the major exemption is that developing countries that had unbound ordinary tariffs, could offer tariff bindings instead of going through the process of tariffication:

    • A further exemption is a concession that was negotiated towards the end of the Uruguay Round, primarily as a result of the reluctance on certain Asian countries, Japan and the Republic of Korea in particular, to liberalise trade in rice.

    Annex 5 describes the further conditions under which countries have been permitted to continue using non-tariff barriers to trade. Special Treatment, as this exemption is called, is only allowed for products that have been specifically mentioned in the Country Schedules as deserving such treatment (i.e. marked with the symbol 'ST-Annex 5').

    Section A of the Annex describes the general conditions for the exemption designed to allow the maintenance of NTBs in certain circumstances. The provisions specify a range of criteria which have to be met concerning the proportion of imports in consumption (i.e. less than 3 percent), the provision of enhanced minimum access commitments and the use of particular domestic and trade policies. In particular, effective production restricting policies must be in place, and no export subsidies must have been used since 1986.

    • Any agricultural commodity or product is included in the provision, although Section B of the Annex modifies these conditions in the case of developing countries, which may apply for Special Treatment under less demanding minimum access conditions if it concerns a primary agricultural product that is the predominant staple in the traditional diet of the country.

    The effect of Section B is to provide developing countries wishing to protect sensitive agricultural commodities behind non-tariff barriers, with greater protection than would be the case under section A. At the same time, it was always unlikely that any developing countries would be applying production restricting measures for their basic foods, and thus be in a position to make use of this exemption.

    3.2.4 Special safeguards provisions

    Another important exemption from the usual market access commitments is the inclusion of Special Safeguard Provisions (SSP), described in Article 5 of the Agreement. This can be applied in two circumstances:

    • in order to prevent a large surge in the volume of imports; or,
    • to avoid the depressing effect on domestic prices of a sharp fall in import prices.
    In both cases, normal tariffs may be supplemented by additional duties when actual import volumes rise above a specified Trigger level (Paragraph 1.(a)), or when import prices, denominated in domestic currency, fall below a certain trigger level (Paragraph 1.(b)).

    In order to apply this concession to a particular commodity, the commodity must be marked in the Country Schedule with the symbol "SSG" (paragraph 1). Apart from the 'triggers' or conditions which merit the use of this concession, the limitations in its use are as follows:

    • The maximum additional duty permitted is specified as being a value not exceeding 30 percent of the normal level of the customs duty in effect during the year in which the SSP is invoked.
    • The additional duty may not be levied beyond the end of the year in which it has been imposed.

    Quantitative trigger level

    The formula describing the method for calculating the quantitative trigger can be found in Paragraph 4 of Article 5. It is described below.

    Box 3.2: Quantitative trigger levels

    The price trigger level

    The reference price for calculating the price trigger level is defined in a footnote to paragraph 1(a) as being in general:

    • The average unit value of the c.i.f. price during the 1986-88 base period, expressed in domestic currency.

    But, it may also be:

    • An 'appropriate' price in terms of quality of the product and its stage of processing.

    There is thus a degree of vagueness in how the trigger price should be established. Countries were not required to include intended trigger prices in their Country Schedules.

    The formula for calculating the permitted level of the additional duty is provided in Paragraph 5. The value of this additional duty is dependent upon the degree to which the import price falls below the trigger level. This is outlined in Box 3.3:

    Box 3.3: Additional duty when price trigger level is exceeded

    To a certain extent the mechanism acts in the same way as a variable levy, in that as the import price falls the levy can be increased so as to dampen the price effect on the domestic market. However, it does not completely offset the fall in import prices, ensuring that domestic prices are not entirely insulated from the effects of changing world market prices.

    3.2.5 Market access commitments: Implementation issues and policy implications

    Having examined in detail the Agreement's provisions regarding market access, we now turn to the question of how these provisions will affect the trade policies of developing countries, and how the new policy constraints may affect their farm protection in the short and longer term.

    Converting NTBs to tariff equivalents

    The idea behind converting non-tariff barriers to trade into tariff equivalents, suggests that tariffication (as opposed to tariff reduction) should not have any immediate effect upon absolute levels of protection, since the rationale behind tariffication is to convert NTBs into a tariff that provides an equivalent level of protection to that existing by virtue of NTBs.

    However, in so far as the levels of protection provided during the base period (1986-88) (for which the tariff equivalents have been calculated) differ from those actually prevailing during the period immediately prior to the start of the implementation period in 1995, tariffication could, in theory, have had an immediate effect upon levels of protection at the beginning of the implementation period.

    • If protection during the base period had been higher than in, for example, 1994 the application of the maximum permitted tariff at the beginning of the implementation period (i.e. the base rate of duty) would have provided a higher level of protection than that which prevailed immediately prior to the implementation period.

    That is not to say, though, that countries have immediately deployed the maximum permissible tariff at the onset of the implementation period; in many cases the tariff applied (i.e. the actual rate of duty) has remained lower than the base rate of duty.

    It is apparent, therefore, that where levels of protection have fallen, or remained the same, since the base period, the process of tariffication need not have had any immediate effect on the level of protection provided to agricultural producers via trade policy.

    • If however, the level of protection during the base period had been lower than in 1994, the introduction in 1995 of tariffs (based upon levels of protection during the base period) would have the immediate effect of suddenly exposing domestic producers to greater competition from imports.

    Extending this notion further, one can also see that the effect of tariff cuts during the implementation period will also depend on how high the base rate of duty is compared with the actual rate of duty. To summarise:

    • Where the base rate of duty is high relative to the actual rate of duty, the effect of a cut in the bound rate of duty may not have a profound impact upon levels of protection. Clearly, the closer the actual rate of duty is to the base rate of duty, the more likely it is that the reduction requirements will have a binding effect.

    High levels of protection during the base period give rise to high base rates of duty

    The conversion of NTBs into their tariff equivalents should, according to the Modalities, have been based upon the difference between the domestic price and world price (border price) during the base period, expressed in domestic currency. The larger the difference is between the two, the greater the protection afforded by the NTBs, and the higher the resulting tariff equivalent.

    In fact, the gap between world market prices and domestic prices in many developed countries was in many cases quite high during the 1986-88 base period, in so far as the world-market prices of major agricultural products were on the whole quite low, when compared to longer-run averages and more recent price trends. Additionally, the relatively low value of the dollar during the base period, had the effect of reducing the world price further, when expressed in domestic currency.

    • In general, then, the choice of 1986-88 as the base period has tended to result in high base rates of duty, when compared to actual rates of duty, and this has, on the whole, softened the impact of tariffication and cuts in bound tariff rates, at least for the duration of the implementation period.

    'Dirty tariffication'

    Another reason why base rates of duty are likely to be quite high relates to what has been called 'dirty tariffication'. This expression describes the situation where countries have deliberately overestimated the levels of protection provided by NTBs in order to increase their operative base rate of duty resulting from tariffication. This has allegedly occurred because the task of converting NTBs into binding tariffs has been left to each individual country concerned. Clearly, countries wishing to retain scope for imposing high levels of protection for particular products, will have found it in their interests to be selective about the data they used for conversion.

    In other words the conversion process could have been manipulated in such a way as to lead to a higher base rate of duty, than would be the case had the conversion been conducted in an unbiased fashion. Yet, so long as the results were not challenged during the verification process, which in general they were not, the resulting tariffs became legally binding from the point at which they were submitted to the WTO as part of the Country Schedules.

    • It is argued, therefore, that the tariffication procedures gave countries considerable opportunity to maintain high levels of protection on sensitive products. At the same time, it must be noted that the method used in calculating the tariff equivalent, the price wedge, is the minimum level that trade measures could be evaluated at.

    It should also be noted that if there had been no NTBs and tariffs with water in them (i.e. higher than required to give a certain level of protection), this would have resulted in higher tariffs than by using tariffication. The extent of 'dirty tariffication' is much disputed, and difficult to demonstrate. In any case, given that the contents of the Country Schedules now provide the legal framework for the implementation of the Agreement, the issue is academic.

    Some implications of the market access provisions

    It is very difficult to provide any firm diagnosis on the likely outcomes of the market access provisions. Much will depend on the manner of implementation. In particular on:

    • The policy priorities of individual countries, especially in the context of economic reform programmes;
    • The interpretation of tariff commitments with regard to minimum access requirements and the allocation of TRQs
    • Whether tariff reduction should reflect the 'spirit' of the Agreement or the 'letter'.

    Structural adjustment programmes

    As mentioned above, the binding nature of tariffication and tariff reduction depends largely upon the difference between actual rates of duty and base rates of duty. The above paragraphs suggest that base rates of duty are likely to be fairly high due to the choice of the base period, and in some cases because of 'dirty tariffication'.

    Equally important, however, is the fact that actual, but usually unbound, tariff rates in some developing countries are in many cases currently lower than base rates of duty, which are bound, as a result of Structural Adjustment Programmes (SAPs), that exist independently of the WTO agreement.

    • The effect of the Agreement should not be perceived as minimal in this context, however, since the binding of tariffs results in increased transparency and certainty of the import regime. Thus, it has a value to exporters that can be reflected in an increase in the level of tariff. In other words, other traders could equate a higher bound tariff to a lower unbound tariff.
    • Nevertheless, where SAPs have been rigorously pursued since the base period, and given that the conditionality attached to SAPs by the World Bank and other donors, generally encourages the tariffication of NTBs and the reduction of tariffs, it is not unlikely that, in many cases, protectionism has been already reduced to below base period levels.

    Such SAPs are, in the short term, likely to place a greater constraint upon protectionist policies than are bindings under the WTO. In the longer term, however, tariff reforms under the WTO, are likely to be more influential, in that they are part of a permanent agreement, that will outlive SAPs, and prevent reversion to NTBs and higher levels of protection.

    It will, in other words, provide a ceiling beyond which protectionism may not rise. Such a ceiling did not previously exist; moreover, in creating the ceiling, the process of tariffication also introduced the possibility of lowering it, and this is likely to be one of tasks that future WTO negotiating rounds will be concerned with.

    Globalised tariff cuts

    The effect of the cuts agreed in the Uruguay Round will be reduced, to an extent by the high level of the base rate of duty, and by trade policy reforms that have occurred since the base period. However the manner in which the base rates are to be cut may also act to further reduce the impact.

    • The commitment to cut the overall level of tariffs by 24 percent (36 percent in the case of developed countries) is based upon the unweighted average of all tariffs. That is to say, commodities in which the volume of production and trade is disproportionately large, are not provided with any additional weighting as far as tariff cuts are concerned.
    • Nor is any additional weight placed on cutting high tariffs versus the cutting of low tariffs.

    For example, if a minor commodity is subject to a base rate duty of just 1 percent, a 100 percent cut in the tariff will receive the same weight, as far as global tariff reduction commitments are concerned, as a 100 percent cut in the 200 percent duty on a major commodity.

    If, for example, we assume a 100 percent tariff cut for the former, and just a 10 percent cut for the latter, the tariff on the minor commodities will have fallen from 1 percent to zero, whilst the tariff on the major commodity will have fallen from 200 to 180 percent. The average tariff reduction will equal : (100+100+10+10)/4 = 55, which easily meets the global reduction obligations.

    • As a result, developing countries theoretically have been able to apply the minimum tariff cut of 10 percent to their most important and most sensitive products, on which existing tariffs are likely to be the highest, whilst easily fulfilling the 24 percent global reduction commitment by making substantial tariff cuts on their least sensitive products: on which existing tariffs are, in any case, already likely to be fairly low.
    In the event, few developing countries took advantages of this possibility in their schedules, in contrast to developed countries, where this reduction minimising effect was more common. As a result, nevertheless, the market access provisions may not have a very great immediate impact on the overall volume of imports, and high levels of protection will have been maintained on some countries most sensitive commodities.

    Minimum access

    The extent to which minimum access requirements will reduce this protection and encourage new imports is uncertain, and depends largely upon the pre-existing level of imports, and the commitments that have been made in the Country Schedules. At a minimum level of just 3 percent of domestic consumption rising to 5 percent, if the rules were followed closely, the impact of these commitments may not be very substantial. In any case, the minimum access provisions only apply to countries that tariffied, and not many developing countries followed this path.

    • In any case, as suggested above, there is a certain amount of confusion and ambiguity surrounding minimum access commitments, and how they should be implemented. Their effect on developing country policy is, therefore, still somewhat unclear at this stage.

    Conclusion

    This section has highlighted the fact that the Agreement and the Modalities both provided countries with some opportunity to avoid offering the sort of tariff concessions that would lead to a major increase in their level of imports. There is certainly evidence to suggest that some developed countries (e.g. EU, USA) have taken advantage of such opportunity.

    In addition, the Special Safeguard Provisions provide countries with additional protection against surges in the volume of imports, or a fall in world prices, in the event that bound tariff rates prove insufficient for this purpose.

    However, there are difficulties with generalising about the policy implications of market access commitments: the contents of the Country Schedules, that determine these commitments, vary considerably from one country to another, and from product to product.

    In the longer term, the tariffication of agricultural trade barriers in the Uruguay Round, could act as a foundation for much deeper cuts in agricultural protection. But, at this point in time the overall effect of the Uruguay Round's market access commitments on the trade and agricultural policies of developing countries would not appear to be very substantial, at least in terms of the protection that they are able to afford to domestic producers.

    • The main benefits lie in the greater transparency that is provided by tariffs, when compared to NTBs. This should provide both traders and policy makers with easier access to knowledge of the levels of protection being imposed in the various sub-sectors of the agricultural economy.

    An additional possible long-term effect of market access commitments might be felt by developing country exporters. Through the reduction the margin between the preferential tariff rates currently enjoyed by some developing country exporters, and the tariffs paid by other countries in developed country export markets.

    • The narrowing of this margin is a process that is likely to continue in the long term, as the level of bound tariffs falls, and squeezes the competitive edge hitherto enjoyed by the exporters receiving preferential treatment.

    3.3 Domestic support commitments

    The importance of the Agreement on Agriculture with regard to domestic policy lies in it being the first time that a close link between domestic and trade policies has been formally recognised. Although the current implications for developing countries may, in most cases, be limited, the future significance lies in the fact that, for the signatories, the Agreement enshrines in international trade law limitations on domestic policy formation, and places constraints on the room for manoeuvre of policy makers. Thus, policies which 'distort' agricultural trade are likely to be increasingly untenable.

    At the same time, it is apparent that the agreement is primarily designed to affect domestic policies in developed countries where, in many cases, export subsidies have been used abundantly, and where domestic agricultural policies are frequently geared to the subsidisation of agricultural production. In contrast, in many developing countries the sum total of policy intervention results in the taxation of the sector, particularly of the export producing sub-sector. In contrast to commitments to subsidy reduction, there is no provision in the Agreement which requires countries to reduce the volume of taxation.

    3.3.1 Developing country exemptions

    As noted above, the domestic support commitments are, in general, far less demanding on the agricultural policies of developing countries, than they are on those of developed countries. This is because:

    • developing country agricultural policies have on the whole tended to tax the agricultural sector, rather than support it; and
    • the Agreement recognises that agricultural support policies in developing countries are often justified on the basis of their being part of the broader economic development agenda.

    Two important exemptions from domestic support reduction commitments for developing countries are provided in Article 6 paragraph 2 of the Agreement:

    • investment subsidies which are generally available to agriculture;
    • agricultural input subsidies generally available to low-income or resource-poor producers.
    Thus, domestic support meeting these criteria shall not be required to be included in the calculation of the current AMS.

    Least-developed countries, on the other hand, are exempt from all domestic support reduction commitments, but may not exceed the Total AMS as established for the base period (1986-88).

    The aggregate measure of support (AMS), the indicator used by the GATT/WTO in order to quantify and reduce levels of domestic support, was discussed in Chapter 2. The Agreement, it was noted, commits its signatories to calculate the Total AMS for the base period (1986-1988): the Base Total AMS, and then, in the case of developed countries, to cut this by 20 percent during the 6 year implementation period.

    • A further concession for developing countries is that the obligation is reduced to a 13.3 percent cut in Total AMS (two-thirds of the developed country commitment), spread over 10 years.

    An important consideration in reviewing the implications of AMS reductions is the fact that although most developing countries have no AMS reductions to make, the outcome of a very low or zero base Total AMS means that most developing countries cannot in the future introduce any price distorting support unless the policy falls within one of the specific exemptions.

    3.3.2 Exemptions from AMS commitments: 'Green Box' policies

    Chapter 2 introduced the concept of 'green box' policies; these being policies that are exempted from the AMS calculation by virtue of their being deemed not to have distortionary effects on trade. We will now look in more detail at the 'green box' and the AMS calculation, with reference to the relevant parts of the Agreement's text.

    A full account of the 'green box' exemptions to domestic support reduction commitments, is given in Annex 2 of the Agreement. For a policy to be excluded from the calculation of AMS, and hence from reduction commitments, it must be deemed to:

    • 'have no, or at most minimal, trade-distorting effects or effects on production';
    In addition, the domestic support involved through the particular policy must meet the following two criteria:

    • it must be provided through a publicly-funded government not involving transfers from consumers; and
    • must not have the effect of providing price support to producers.
    If all these conditions are met, the policy may be categorised as in the 'green box'.

    Policies that may be included within the 'green box' are reviewed below. They are a summary of the list that appears in Annex 2 of the Agreement, to which readers may refer in order to see the exact text of the agreement.

    General services

    Policies under this heading involve programmes that provide services or benefits to agriculture or the rural community, but which do not involve direct payments to producers or processors. They include:

    • research programmes: general, environmental and product-specific;
    • pest & disease-control measures;
    • training facilities and courses;
    • extension and advisory services;
    • inspection services, including health, safety and standardisation monitoring;
    • marketing and promotion services including provision of market information;
    • infrastructural services, excluding subsidised provision of on farm facilities other than for the reticulation of generally available public utilities.
    Public stockholding for food security purposes

    This exemption refers to expenditures (or revenues forgone) in relation to the accumulation and holding of stocks of products which form an integral part of a food security programme identified in national legislation. Expenditures may be excluded from AMS calculations provided that the following conditions are met:

    • the volume and accumulation of such stocks must correspond to predetermined targets related solely to food security;
    • the process of accumulation and disposal is financially transparent;
    • food purchases by the government are made at current market prices;
    • sales from food security stocks shall be made at no less than the current domestic market price for the product and quality in question, except in the case of subsidised food provision to the rural and urban poor of developing countries.
    Domestic food aid

    Policies aimed at providing domestic food aid to vulnerable sections of the community can also be excluded from the AMS calculations provided that:

    • eligibility to receive food aid is subject to clearly-defined criteria related to nutritional objectives;
    • the food aid is in the form of direct provision of food to those concerned, or the provision of the means to buy food either at market or subsidised prices;
    • food purchases by the government are made at current market prices.
    Direct payments to producers

    Certain types of direct payment to producers may be included in the 'green box' category provided that they 'have no, or at most minimal, trade-distorting effects or effects on production' and provided that the size of such payments, in a given year, is not related to:

    • the type or volume of production undertaken by the producer in any year after the base year;
    • the prices, domestic or international of any production undertaken after the base year;
    • the factors of production employed in any year after the base year.

    The types of direct payment that are permitted are listed below:

    ==> De-coupled income support

    This implies that for direct payments aimed at supporting the incomes of producers to be exempt from AMS calculations, it is important that they do not influence production decisions i.e., they should be "de-coupled" from production, and should not, therefore, have any effect upon what is produced or on how much is produced.

    ==> Government financial participation in income insurance and income safety-net programmes

    This exemption is provided on the condition that such insurance only covers income losses in excess of 30% of average gross income and only covers 70% of that loss. Again, these payments should not relate to the volume or type of production, but should be based solely upon income.

    ==> Payments for relief from natural disasters

    For payments of this kind to be exempt, they must be part of the assistance provided in response to an officially declared natural disaster in which the resulting production losses exceed 30 percent of the average production in the previous 3 years (or 5 years, excluding the years in which the highest and lowest production figures occurred)

    ==> Structural adjustment provided through producer retirement programmes

    These include payments made to producers as part of a retirement programme in which the producers desist totally and permanently from the production of marketable agricultural commodities.

    ==> Structural adjustment through resource retirement programmes or through investment aids

    These exemptions include direct payments made under resource retirement programmes, and with respect to investment assistance must be designed to assist the financial or physical restructuring of a producer's operations in response to 'structural disadvantages'. They may also be based on a programme for the re-privatization of agricultural land.

    ==> Payments under environmental programmes

    This provision is aimed at allowing producers to be compensated for financial losses incurred as a result of clearly defined government environmental and conservation programmes. These include, for example, programmes that require producers to adopt particular production methods or inputs for the purpose of achieving environmental objectives. As such they are exempt from the usual condition that 'AMS exempt' direct payments should not be determined by the type and method of production. The amount of the payment is limited to the extra costs or loss of income resulting from compliance with the government programme.

    ==> Payments under regional assistance programmes

    Payments in this category are limited to those made to producers in clearly defined 'disadvantaged' regions, in which the disadvantages "arise out of more than temporary circumstances". The region in question must be "a clearly designated contiguous geographical area with a definable economic and administrative identity".

    3.3.3 Other exemptions from AMS calculations

    The 'green box' exemptions listed above are probably the best known exemptions from domestic support reduction commitments. While they are of considerable importance to developed country agricultural policy, there are few groups of policies in the 'green box' category which are of major significance in developing countries. Other exemptions include the de minimis and 'blue box' provisions, of which the former is by far the most important.

    ==> The 'de minimis' provision

    Described in Article 6, this provision offers policy makers additional room for manoeuvre. We discussed previously that where the AMS for a particular product constitutes less than 10 percent (5 percent for developed countries) of the total value of production of that commodity, the de minimis clause exempts that support from inclusion in the calculation of the Total AMS. This exemption also applies to non-product specific support.

    • It is worth emphasizing that the de minimis provisions are specified in relation to total production, not to total marketed production. Thus, in developing countries where a large percentage of total production is retained on the farm, the proportion of marketed production that subsidies need to exceed before AMS commitments come into effect will be considerably higher than 10 percent.
    ==> The 'blue box' provision

    This provision exempts direct payments made in conjunction with production limiting programmes, is of direct relevance to developed countries, (e.g. EU and US set-aside payments), but is of much less concern to developing countries where production limiting programmes are not at all widespread.

    3.3.4 Calculating the total AMS

    This section provides guidelines on the methodology for calculating AMS values. It summarizes the rules laid out in Annex 3 and Annex 4 of the Agreement. The basic idea behind the AMS calculation is to quantify, in monetary terms, the support provided by all policies that do not fall within any of the exempt categories discussed above. Only when such quantification has taken place, can a measurable reduction take place.

    • Even if a country has not AMS to reduce, it must regularly calculate the amount spent to make sure that it does not exceed the de minimis level.
    Current versus base period AMS

    Verifiable AMS reductions require, firstly, that base period AMS values be calculated and, secondly, that current AMS values be established on an annual basis in order to evaluate compliance with the reduction commitments.

    • The Base Total AMS, that is, the value of the Total AMS during the base period, was calculated in order that reduction commitments could be included in the Country Schedules. The base period is generally taken to be the period from 1986-88.

    However, the modalities included a provision that allowed countries to gain credit for reforms in domestic support that had taken place during that period (e.g. the EU's CAP reforms). Hence, countries were given the option of using 1986 as the base period. The EU, the USA and Japan all took advantage of this provision, since by raising the level at which their domestic support started, their AMS reduction commitments were made less demanding.

    The fixed external reference price

    Since the calculation of AMS values entails the quantification of domestic support measures in monetary terms, this raises the question of which prices should be used in order to establish the appropriate monetary values.

    The answer provided in the Agreement is that the price adopted should be what is referred to as the fixed external reference price. This is expressed in national currency, and defined as the average price prevailing during the base period.

    • These prices are average f.o.b prices for the agricultural product where the country is a net exporter of that product, and average c.i.f. prices where the country is a net importer.
    • The fixed external reference price is used both for the evaluation of the current AMS and the baseline AMS. It is expressed in domestic currency using a market exchange rate appropriate during the base period.

    Box 3.4: Implications of the fixed reference price

    Calculating the total AMS

    The total AMS is established by summing the value of the product-specific AMS, the non-product specific AMS and the Equivalent Measure of Support. The methodologies for establishing the values of these is presented in the sections below. A Base Total AMS has already been calculated and notified in the Country Schedules. Current Total AMS values are calculated during the implementation period in order to establish compliance with reduction commitments. The following rules apply to AMS calculations:

    • Subsidies shall include both budgetary outlays and revenues forgone by governments or their agents.
    • Support at both the national and sub-national level shall be included.
    • Specific agricultural levies or fees paid by producers shall be deducted from the AMS.
    The product-specific AMS

    The Agreement requires that AMS values be calculated on a product-specific basis for each agricultural commodity that receives:

    • market price support;
    • non-exempt direct payments;
    • or support provided by other non-exempt measures.
    The calculation of the AMS for individual products requires that a value be established for each of these three different types of support. The product-specific AMS is then obtained by summing the three resulting values. The methodology for calculating these three values is presented below. Non-exempt direct payments and measures are those that are not exempted from inclusion within the AMS calculation, by either the 'green box', 'blue box' or de minimis provisions.

    ==> Market price support

    Market price support is to be calculated by establishing the difference between the fixed external reference price and the applied administered price, and multiplying the resulting figure by the quantity of production eligible to receive the applied administrative price.

    Budgetary payments made to maintain this gap, such as buying-in or storage costs, are not included in the AMS. It is worth noting that the market price support component of the AMS applies only to products for which an administered price is actually set. Where a wedge between the market price and the fixed external reference price is maintained by import barriers alone, the market price support element is not included in the AMS calculation.

    ==> Non-exempt direct payments - e.g. deficiency payments

    Support provided by non-exempt direct payments takes one of two forms for the purpose of calculating AMS values:

    • Support aimed at maintaining an administered price. This includes, for example, deficiency payments that are made to farmers in order that they may receive a minimum guaranteed price for their production.
    The value of this type of support is measured by calculating the difference between the administered price and the fixed external reference price, and then multiplying the resulting figure by the volume of production eligible to receive the administered price. Alternatively the total value of the budgetary outlays involved in this support may be used as the measure of support.

    • In addition, there are non-exempt direct payments that are not aimed specifically at maintaining an administered price level.

    In these cases the total value of budgetary outlays are used as the measure of support.

    Other non-exempt measures

    These include input subsidies and other measures such as marketing-cost reduction measures.

    The value of these measures are established either by using (a) the value of government budgetary outlays, or (b) the difference between the price of the good or service and a representative market price for a similar good or service multiplied by the quantity of the good or service.

    In the case where the subsidy is covered entirely by government budgetary outlays, then the former methodology (a) is used. Where this is not the case, for example where government interventions in the market reduce the price of the good or service, the latter methodology (b) is applied. What constitutes "a representative market price for a similar good or service" in (b) is not clearly defined, and probably offers room for manoeuvre.

    Non-product specific AMS

    Support which is non-product specific shall be totalled into one non-product-specific AMS. It is not possible to calculate levels of market support as in the case of product-specific support. However, non-exempt direct payments, which are non-product specific, and therefore not aimed specifically at maintaining an administered price level, may be calculated on the basis of total budgetary outlays; other non-exempt measures may also be calculated in this manner.

    Equivalent measure of support

    The equivalent measure of support is to be calculated for all products for which market price support exists, but for which it is impracticable to calculate a market price support component (as described above) for the AMS. For these products market price support is calculated "using the applied administered price and the quantity of production eligible to receive that price or, where this is not practicable, on budgetary outlays used to maintain the producer price." To this value is then added the support provided by non-exempt direct payments and other non-exempt measures, which is calculated in the manner described above.

    3.3.5 Domestic support commitments: Implementation issues and policy implications

    As was noted previously, the attention paid to domestic support by the Uruguay negotiators came about as a result of the policy excesses in developed countries, and the trade distortions that the high levels of support there have caused.

    In developing countries domestic policies have typically taxed producers rather than supporting them, and the value of the Total AMS, in terms of both the base period level and the current level, would be, in many cases negative, if carried to the logical conclusion.

    Furthermore, since the product-specific and non-product-specific AMS values, are in such cases, often well below the de minimis levels beyond which AMS reduction commitments start to become effective, many developing countries have found that domestic support commitments have rarely posed a constraint at this point in time.

    Nevertheless, there are in developing countries many domestic agricultural policies that should be included in the AMS calculation, particularly in the calculation of product-specific AMS values, even if it is subsequently found that the support they provide falls below de minimis levels, and need not, therefore, be subject to discipline.

    At the same time, as most developing countries have zero AMS, the constraint may arise in the future if some price distorting support is introduced, when the zero base AMS will act as a ceiling on such support which is over and above the de minimis level. The following should therefore be noted:

    • The Current Total AMS may exceed the Base Total AMS as a consequences of reducing implicit taxation even though the value of the latter may be effectively negative. For example, current AMS values could become less negative, or even positive, through the removal of the implicit taxation that is frequently a feature of policy in developing countries at present, and which Structural Adjustment Policies are trying to discourage.
    This will not be permitted under the provisions of the domestic support commitments, which, in theory, forbids countries from exceeding base period levels after taking into account the de minimis exemptions, and commits many developing countries (least developed countries excluded) to reducing the Total AMS. This appears to be an anomaly.

    Certainly de minimis provisions will exclude subsidies that fall below the value of 10 percent of total production from the AMS calculation, and this means that the Base Total AMS is bound at zero for those countries that implicitly tax their agricultural sectors. Furthermore, so long as future increases in subsidies do not exceed the "de minimis" threshold, then Current AMS will also remain at zero.

    • However, if the subsidies begin to exceed the "de minimis" threshold they will translate into positive values of Current Total AMS, and will therefore be in breach of GATT/WTO rules.

    This implies that, leaving aside the problem of AMS reduction commitments, developing countries that are at present "taxing" their agricultural sectors will be bound never to raise their support levels above those excluded from the AMS calculation under the "de minimis" provisions.

    Before continuing, it is worthwhile noting that AMS measurements differ substantially from a more widely known and commonly used measure of support, the Producer Subsidy Equivalent (PSE). The following Box details the main points of difference. In essence these stem from the fact that the AMS is a much weaker, or less complete measure, and does not take account of a number of some significant forms of domestic support. It also differs in the role played by the external reference price which, as discussed above, makes the measure unaffected by exchange rate and world price movements.

    Box 3.5: A comparison of PSE and AMS measurements

    The following sections outline some of the policies frequently employed by developing country governments, which may in future, if not at present, be affected by WTO commitments on domestic support.

    Output price policies

    Government administered output pricing has often been a major feature of developing country agricultural policy. However, unlike in developed countries where administered prices have generally been higher than world market prices, thereby providing support to agricultural producers, administered prices in developing countries have often been lower than international prices and have, therefore, effectively taxed producers. Accordingly, as noted above, the market price support component of the product-specific AMS has, for many agricultural commodities, typically been negative.

    Traded input price policies

    In an attempt to offset low output prices policy makers have often sought to provide subsidised inputs. These are frequently directed at specific commodities, as part of production packages that include seeds, fertilizers, pesticides and machinery, and credit. In such cases the subsidy would be included in the product-specific part of the AMS calculation, although the value of these subsidies often fail to offset the negative value of the market price support component of the AMS. Where input subsidies are not directed at specific commodities they would be included in the non-product-specific component of the AMS. It should be remembered that:

    • Input subsidies that are targeted at "low-income or resource-poor producers" are exempt from the AMS calculation, provided that they are made 'generally' available to these groups. How the expression of 'low-income or resource-poor' is to be interpreted is not specified in the Agreement, leaving it open to governments to make their own interpretations.
    Non-traded input pricing

    Subsidies on inputs that are non-traded, such as those on credit, water and electricity are also subject to inclusion within the AMS calculation, although it is not made entirely clear how the value of such subsidies should be calculated.

    • Credit subsidies will be particularly difficult to calculate, especially in the context of high inflation when the level of subsidy changes rapidly. Further problems arise because the level of subsidy is dependent upon the length of time for which credit is extended and the degree to which loans are repaid on time.

    Marketing interventions

    Governments in developing countries are frequently involved in marketing, either through the direct provision of marketing services by state agencies, or through the public funding of various marketing facilities.

    • Where these activities affect the market price of either inputs or outputs through, for example, administered pricing, the resulting price distortions are captured in the product specific AMS, or, in the case of input pricing measures through calculating the value of other non-exempt measures.

    Otherwise marketing interventions are excluded from the AMS calculation.

    Other public investments

    Most other public investments in the agricultural sector of developing countries are exempt from AMS commitments. They gain their exemption either through the specific exemptions accorded to developing countries, or through the 'green box' provisions:

    • Developing countries do not, for example, need to modify policies concerned with research and extension; and provision of physical infrastructure, such as roads, irrigation structures, and marketing facilities.

    3.4 Export policies: Subsidies and restrictions

    3.4.1 Export Subsidy Commitments

    As with domestic support commitments, the commitments on export subsidies have been introduced into the Agreement principally in response to developed country policies. Export subsidies have been a major component of agricultural policies in the EU and the USA, but have not, on the whole, played a very important role in developing countries. Consequently, the Agreement's export subsidy commitments do not, generally speaking, have major policy implications for developing countries. The definition of what constitutes an export subsidy, for the purposes of the Agreement is provided in Article 9. The following list summarises the definitions given in the relevant paragraphs:

    • The provision by governments or their agencies of direct subsidies, including payments-in-kind, to a firm, to an industry, to producers of an agricultural product, to a cooperative or other association of such producers, or to a marketing board, contingent on export performance.
    • The sale or disposal for export by governments or their agencies of non-commercial stocks of agricultural products at a price lower than the comparable price charged for a like product to buyers in the domestic market.
    • Payments on the export of an agricultural product that are financed by virtue of governmental action, whether or not a charge on the public account is involved, including payments that are financed from the proceeds of a levy imposed on the agricultural product concerned, or on an agricultural product from which the exported product is derived.
    • The provision of subsidies to reduce the costs of marketing exports of agricultural products (other than widely available export promotions and advisory services) including handling, upgrading and other processing costs, and the costs of international transport and freight.
    • Internal transport and freight charges on export shipments, provided or mandated by governments, on terms more favourable than for domestic shipments.

    3.4.2 Developing country exemptions

    Developing countries receive some temporary and limited exemptions with regards to the export subsidies outlined above. Specifically they are permitted, during the implementation period only, to encourage exports with subsidies aimed at reducing the cost of marketing, processing and transport, provided they are not applied in a manner which would circumvent reduction commitments.

    3.4.3 Reduction commitments

    For those developing countries that do subsidise exports, the Uruguay Round agreement requires:

    • Budgetary expenditure on export subsidies for the base period (1986-90 or 1991-92, whichever is higher) to be reduced by 24 percent over the ten year implementation period.
    • Reductions are also required in the volume of subsidised commodities: a 14 percent reduction of the base period level over ten years.
    • Reductions are to be implemented in equal annual installments on a commodity specific basis. Least-developed countries are not obliged to make any reductions.

    Again, as with other aspects of the agreement, the specific implementation rules were often only included in the Modalities, with the result that commitments are only binding to the extent that they appear in the Country Schedules.

    3.4.4 Export restraints

    Export policies in developing countries have generally concentrated more on export restraints, than on export subsidies. These have taken the form of taxes, quotas and prohibitions.

    The Agreement introduces restrictions on the use of export restraints, where such restraints relate to foodstuffs. However, these restrictions do not apply to developing countries unless they are 'net exporters' of the particular foodstuff in question. At the same time, no definitions is offered as to what a 'net exporter' of a particular foodstuff might be in these circumstances. This will have to await clarification by the WTO when such a case arises.

    The Agreement disciplines on Export Prohibitions and Restrictions are found in Article 12. For those countries, including developing countries, that are net exporters of a particular foodstuff, the following provisions apply to their use of export restraints:

    • The country instituting the export prohibition or restriction must give 'due consideration' to the effects of such prohibition or restriction on importing countries' food security.

    • Before any country institutes an export prohibition or restriction, it must give notice in writing, as far in advance as possible, to the Committee on Agriculture, giving information regarding the nature and the duration of the restraint. Additionally, the country must provide this information to any other member country with an interest in the outcome and which requests prior discussion.

    The Agreement allows for sanctions by other member countries if these two conditions are not adhered to. It does not, however, suggest what these sanctions should be.

    Checklist for Chapter 3