Previous Page Table of Contents Next Page


PART III. ISSUES IN AGRICULTURAL COMMODITY MARKETS


Price developments for basic food commodities
Oil prices and agricultural commodity prices
Tariff peaks in agricultural markets and tariff cutting formulae
Recent trends in deficits and surpluses in basic food commodities in Africa
Impact of the Uruguay Round Agreements of relevance to the agricultural sector: Winners and losers

Price developments for basic food commodities

Introduction

The most striking feature of the developments observed in the international markets of basic food commodities during the last decade is the prominent price spikes that occurred for most of them in the mid-1990s (see Figure 3.1)[5]. Although, the downward trend since then has been reversed for dairy products from 1999, the prices of cereals, meat and oilcrop products continue to be depressed at levels that have not been seen for nearly two decades. Indeed, as measured by the relevant FAO indices, the average annual changes in the international prices since 1995 were -8.8 percent for major grains, -6.6 percent for rice, -6.6 percent for oilseeds, -3.4 percent for meat products and -3.5 percent for dairy products[6].

Figure 3.1: Annual FAO price indices of major food and feed commodity groups

Such strong convergence of price developments during the 1990s[7] is an indication of the commonality of the underlying fundamentals influencing the markets of various basic food commodities, as well as of the strong linkages existing between these markets. Although there were developments unique to each commodity market, these were either exerting pressure that tended to influence the markets in the same direction or not strong enough to overcome the effects of those that were working to influence the markets in the same direction.

Grain markets

Over the past decade, world wheat and coarse grain sectors have witnessed several important developments, some with major implications for international prices. As indicated below, changes in the pattern of trade (i.e. the changing composition of the main importing and exporting countries) and developments in the domestic cereal market of the United States and China have had the most direct impact on the global cereal economy, in general, and on the prevailing depressed state of grain prices, in particular.

Prior to the 1990s, the sharpest year-to-year (as well as intra-year) price swings were triggered by the presence or absence of two dominant, and yet unpredictable, buyers on world markets, namely the former USSR and China. The breakdown of the USSR not only eliminated the world’s largest grain importer from the international scene but also resulted in a significant expansion in unsold grains (hence large inventories) in major exporting countries, which continued to overhang the market through 1995 as other buyers did not fill the void. Between 1990 and 1995, major exporters made greater recourse to export discounts and subsidies in order to reduce their large stocks.

By 1995, however, they had also began reforming their domestic policies in order to deal with chronic problems of over-production. After the sudden price surge in 1995/96, caused by a significant fall in global cereal production, mainly due to weather problems in major exporting countries, export subsidies were no longer necessary and a sharp draw-down of stocks in major exporting countries raised expectations of continued strong prices, a factor which encouraged farmers to produce more grains in the following year. At the same time, a number of net-import producing countries such as Pakistan and India also adopted policies that were successful in encouraging production. In 2000 both India and Pakistan harvested record crops. As a result, both countries shifted from being net importers to net exporters often at relatively low prices which dampened quotations on the world market.

Against the background of strong prices and in compliance with Uruguay Round commitments, the 1995 Farm Bill in the United States, known as the Federal Agricultural Improvement and Reform (FAIR) Act, came into force in April 1996. While the FAIR Act aimed at removing (or decoupling) the link between support payments and farm prices by replacing deficiency payments by direct compensatory payments, the continuing support to the United States farmers in the form of emergency aid, on the top of the compensatory payments, provided enough incentive to farmers to continue growing grains even though the market signals, i.e. prices, were not encouraging.

In the meantime, China, a major wheat importer, continued on its policy to increase domestic production and reduce its dependence on imports. China’s grain policy since the mid-1990s encouraged higher production year after year so that by the late 1990s the country needed to import only small amount of grains. Following a short-lived interval in the mid-1990s, China’s maize production began to exceed domestic demand and this gave rise to a period of export boom. However, driven by the high financial burden of rising inventories along with the country’s bid to join WTO, China started to reform its grain economy, reducing production incentives and lowering its large stocks[8]. These changes resulted in a decline in plantings already in 2000. Beside lower plantings, weather problems also affected production in 2001, which fell well below consumption requirements. However, the shortfall was largely met through the release of stocks rather than by imports. In addition, China continued to export maize, although the decline in maize production was even more substantial. The absence of China as a major wheat importer and its continuing maize sales into the world market have also contributed significantly to the to put downward pressure on international prices.

Rice market

The sharp increases in prices between 1994 and 1996 reflected a sudden rise in import demand by countries that had experienced serious crop shortfalls in that period, including Bangladesh, China, Indonesia and especially Japan, which emerged as the top rice importer in 1994. As a result, the global volume of trade rose substantially and in 1995 surpassed the 20 million tonnes benchmark for the first time. The tightening of the international rice market revived food security concerns among large rice producing/consuming countries, and encouraged Governments to adopt more expansionary production policies. This new policy stance, together with favourable growing conditions, was responsible for the subsequent increases in global paddy production, which reached a new record in 1999.

For many of those countries that had embarked in supportive production policies, gains in output in the second half of the decade largely exceeded growth in domestic requirements, leading to the formation of large surpluses that had to be carried over the next years. As a result, global rice stocks rose substantially, especially at the close of the 1998 and 1999 seasons. Moreover, several of the countries that had been major importers in 1993-96 either cut imports or achieved self-sufficiency and some reverted back to a net exporting position. Purchases by China, for instance, which had soared in 1995 following a very poor 1994/95 harvest, were curbed substantially in 1997, as the country returned to the market as an exporter. In 1998, its exports climbed to 3.8 million tonnes and, have since then remained close to 3 million tonnes, even in 2000 under conditions of falling production, as the country could draw from its very large rice inventories.

While the faltering global import demand and the pressure from large export availabilities had a strong depressing effect on prices in the late part of the 1990s, the high level of protection that characterizes the rice sector did not allow the fall in prices to be fully transmitted onto domestic markets in major producing countries. Instead, Governments continued to shield their country’s rice sectors from falling international prices, by reducing import competition or by promoting exports, either through government-to-government deals, barter arrangements, or credit programmes, all of which tended to exacerbate the drop in prices in 2000. To some extent, commitments taken under the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture hindered the ability of countries like India, the Republic of Korea, Japan or the EC to dispose of their excess supply on the world market other than in the form of commercial sales or food aid. Such constraints did not apply to other major rice market players, such as China, Myanmar or Vietnam, which were not WTO members. However, there is no formal evidence to suggest that these countries subsidized their exports.

Figure 3.2. Monthly FAO index of international rice prices

There are signs, however, that may point to a price recovery soon. Since 2000, global rice production has fallen short of global rice consumption, requiring stocks to be released in a number of countries, especially China. Moreover, a number of countries more exposed to international competition (Argentina, Uruguay) have reacted to the low prices by cutting plantings. In others, Governments are embracing less supportive production policies, especially China, but also Egypt, Japan, the Republic of Korea, Pakistan and Vietnam. Finally, drought conditions currently prevailing in various countries might also support a firming of prices.

Markets for oilcrop products

During the nineties, price developments in the oilseeds complex manifested the usual complex and diverse pattern (see Figure 3.3). Overall, periods of more stable prices alternated with periods of strong price movements. Until the end of 1992 and again between 1996 and mid 1999, prices for oils and meals - linked to one another through the crushing of oilseeds - moved more or less in parallel. By contrast, there have been two exceptional spells, 1993-1995 and 1999-2000, where the oil and meal price indices moved in opposite directions. The market fundamentals underlying price developments during these two periods are outlined below.

In the second half of 1993, international oil prices started rising due to shortfalls in global oil supplies, and decreasing inventories. International oilmeal prices, by contrast, weakened, primarily because of depressed import demand. This situation persisted throughout the following year, when a further tightening of oil supplies and markedly reduced stock levels led to further sharp increases in oil prices, while meal prices remained low due to continued weak import demand particularly in the EC, where agricultural policy changes favoured the use of grains over oilmeals in feed rations, and in Eastern Europe and the CIS, where domestic demand for and imports of oilmeals dropped as a result of low economic growth and of foreign exchange shortages. Eventually, oil prices decreased again in 1995 as, due to improved harvests of high oil-yielding crops, the tightness in global supplies eased and stocks in importing countries were replenished. At the same time, however, meal prices started to climb due to a combination of factors, including a fall in global soybean output, sustained global demand for livestock products and an increase in demand generated by a more favourable meal/grain price ratio following the marked increase in feed grain prices in 1995.

Figure 3.3. Monthly FAO indices of international prices of oils and meals

Toward the beginning of 1998, meal prices, and later also oil prices, came under intense downward pressure. This was mainly the result of a strong recovery in global production of soybeans and other oilcrops (partly related to agricultural support policies applied in certain countries), combined with a slow-down in the expansion of global oil and meal consumption. In the case of oils, prices continued to fall sharply during 1999 and 2000, mainly for two reasons: further good harvests of high oil-yielding crops, and the full recovery of tropical oil production from the adverse effects of El Niño in 1997-98 - both leading to a marked increase in inventories in major exporting countries. Initially, also meal prices continued falling as world soybean production and global oilmeal stocks expanded, and because competition from feed grains increased again following a conspicuous drop in their prices. However, as opposed to oil prices, from mid 1999 onward, international prices for cakes and meals recovered, mainly because the expansion of global oilmeal production came to a halt, with soymeal supplies actually falling short of demand, thereby reversing the situation observed since the end of 1997.

Markets for livestock products

Meat

International meat prices have exhibited a sharp decline during 1997-98 (see Figure 3.4). There were many factors influencing this. They ranged from: the effects of animal productions cycles, particularly for beef; and changing composition of meat trade, caused by changes on the demand side; to high degrees of concentration of international meat imports, making international markets susceptible to shocks occurring in any one of the major importing countries.

Figure 3.4. Monthly FAO index of international meat prices

The analysis of prices in the meat sector, when compared to those of the crops sector, is further complicated by the heterogeneous nature of meat products that currently enter international markets. This makes it difficult to identify representative international prices, which, with the rapidly changing structure of international trade, makes a general meat index quickly lose its relevance for tracking market developments. Keeping these caveats in mind, Figure 3.4 indicates that meat prices have often not followed the same path as those of basic food crops.

An important component of the FAO meat index is the price of beef products, and, hence, the decline in beef prices since the mid-1990s has been an important contributor to the decline in the overall index. Herd liquidation in the United States, the world’s largest importer of beef, beginning in 1996 because of the sharp increases in the prices of feed grains and subsequently oil meals, resulted in reduced import demand and thus contributed to weaker international beef prices. Meanwhile, a stagnant economy in Japan, the second largest import market, led to consumer preferences shifting to lower-value imported beef cuts, such as short plate, brisket, and chuck, adding further downward pressure on average beef prices. This declining trend tentatively reversed itself in 1999 in response to recovery in Asian markets and indications of herd rebuilding in the United States, both of which turned out to be short-lived, maintaining the international prices at their new lows, aided by the re-emergence of the BSE crises in Europe later on.

Additional downward pressure on international meat prices after 1997 was generated by the financial crisis in Russia, in 1997 the world’s largest meat importer and the recipient of more than a quarter of world trade in poultry meat. International poultry prices dropped sharply as a result. Moreover, currency devaluations in Thailand and Brazil, two major poultry meat exporters, contributed to the downward pressure on poultry prices. However, the gradual stabilisation of the Russian economy and animal disease outbreaks in late 2000 and 2001, affecting the availability of beef and pigmeat, could lead to a significant recovery in poultry prices. Similarly, lamb prices, after jumping precipitously in 1996 and 1997 in response to BSE concerns by consumers in Europe, the largest import market for ovine products, are witnessing significant price strength in 2001.

The structure of the global pigmeat market is relatively thin, with trade constituting approximately 3 percent of global production. In addition, it is highly concentrated-two-thirds of world trade determined by only three different import and exports markets - thus making the overall market more vulnerable to individual country market shocks. This was evidenced in 1998 when escalating production in exporting countries at the time of the financial crisis in Russia-the largest meat import market led to a precipitous drop in demand for pigmeat imports, resulting in pig prices in the United States and the EC dropping to 30 year lows. Pigmeat prices have remained low since, probably as a result of restructuring in pigmeat industries in the United States and the EC, with record low prices forcing smaller producers out of business. Lower marginal costs of production as companies increased their size and scale of operations may be allowing product to be sold at lower prices. Some shifting of product preference to lower-value cuts in Japan, may be also maintaining some downward pressure on prices.

Dairy Products

Over the past decade, international prices for dairy products have shown considerable variation (see Figure 3.5). During this period, import demand grew by approximately a third and rose from 5.5 percent to 7.0 percent of world milk production. However, despite the increase in world demand, the amount of milk traded, in relation to total production, remained relatively small. On the export side, the international market for dairy products is characterised by a limited number of exporting countries. While the number of importing countries is greater, a limited group of countries account for a substantial proportion of imports.

Figure 3.5: Monthly FAO index international dairy prices

As a result of the above, relatively small changes in supply or demand in the main exporting and importing countries have been sufficient to produce substantial changes in international prices. Thus, during the latter part of the 1990's, economic adjustments in Asia and the devaluation of the Russian ruble and the Brazilian real were important factors in the lower prices seen during this period. The more recent rise in dairy prices reflects: improved economic conditions in some of the major importing countries; for petroleum-producing countries, increased revenue to fund imports; domestic market conditions in the EC, which led to the reduced availability of surplus dairy products for export; and commitments to reduce the volume and value of subsidised exports arising out of the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture.

Concluding remarks

The prominent spikes in the international prices of most basic food commodities observed in the mid-1990s were essentially due to unfavourable weather conditions that curtailed production in large parts of the globe and led to substantial declines in carryover stocks of the commodities concerned. Subsequent “spill-over” changes were triggered by these spikes, in part due to the strong linkages among the various commodity markets, with, for example, the increase in the prices of feed grains affecting both the meals and livestock sectors. Such widespread climatic influences on production though infrequent, are not exceptional. With declining global inventories of some major food commodities, especially in major exporting countries, moreover, their impact on food security of vulnerable countries may give rise to serious concerns as financial instruments to cope with such sharp shortfalls may not be the best way of coping with physical unavailability of food supplies.

Changes in economic performance in countries in different parts of the world and policy responses at the national level have been superimposed on these to complicate the assessment of the developments over the latter half of the decade. Output increasing effects of price increases combined with relatively slow economic growth in many parts of the world have weakened international prices of food commodities since the mid-1990s, a phenomenon that has been facilitated by increasing integration into the global markets of even the remotest countries. With increasing pressure to reduce accumulated domestic inventories in some countries and policy responses in others to counter the effects of lower returns, the downward pressure on international prices have continued well into the beginning of the new millennium.

It should also be noted that this period has also seen the beginning of the implementation of the Uruguay Round of Agreement on Agriculture. Although the members party to the Agreement have generally kept to their commitments, which however did not lead to substantial changes in policies, the developments described above in the market fundamentals have made it difficult to isolate the contribution that the Agreement has made to those developments.

Oil prices and agricultural commodity prices

Introduction

The issue of whether oil price movements have a significant influence on the markets and prices of internationally-traded agricultural commodities has been discussed in a number of international fora, most recently in the sessions of the FAO intergovernmental groups dealing with natural fibres. However, no clear conclusions have emerged concerning whether oil price changes do have an impact on the prices of other commodities and if so, what form - positive or negative - they might take. It seems likely that if there are linkages, these will vary from commodity to commodity and from country to country. The dynamics of such relationships are also of interest: given the secular downward trend in the prices of many commodities, it may be that any oil price effects are confined to the short-run. These are essentially empirical questions, but there has been little economic analysis of possible linkages to provide empirical evidence either way. This article discusses the nature of possible relationships between oil prices and agricultural commodity prices, and presents the results of some preliminary econometric analysis which tries to test for the existence and significance of any such effects in relation to fibres.

Oil prices are currently (October 2001) averaging just over $20/barrel, some 30 percent lower than one year ago. The 2000 oil price shock appears to have been only temporary: after reaching a peak of more than $30/barrel in September and November of that year, prices have fallen steadily, averaging $28 in 2000 and $25 so far in 2001. While the current international situation makes forecasting particularly problematic, prices had been expected to average $18-19/barrel in the longer term. It should be remembered, however, that the final price of oil is not simply dependent on oil supply and demand, but also includes national taxes and subsidies. For example, in the EC taxes account for two thirds of the retail petrol price. Compensatory changes in national taxes might reinforce international oil price movements by maintaining demand in the face of rising prices.

The macroeconomic consequences of oil price shocks have been widely discussed. While price hikes may be beneficial to the oil-exporting countries, it is generally believed that the effect on overall world output and aggregate demand is adverse. Industrialised countries have succeeded in raising the efficiency of their energy use, partly in response to higher oil prices, but also as a result of environmental concerns, such that oil price shocks are less severe than in the past. The consequences for oil-importing developing countries are more severe, since developing countries tend to use more energy per unit of output - up to twice as much - and this has increased further with industrialisation. The oil import bill therefore generally accounts for a greater share of the current account balance. Meanwhile earnings from exports of many agricultural commodities have trended downwards as prices have fallen, exacerbating the negative impact of increases in oil import bills. However, if there are linkages between the price of oil and the prices of these agricultural commodities, the impact of oil price changes on the balance of payments of oil-importing developing countries may be reinforced or cushioned by the resulting relative price changes. The nature of any such linkages between oil prices and the prices of selected agricultural commodities is explored in this article.

Economic links between oil prices and agricultural commodity prices

This section considers the economic mechanisms through which variations in oil prices might be expected to impact upon agricultural commodity prices. These are multiple and complex, and as noted above, are likely to differ from commodity to commodity and from country to country. It is difficult therefore, a priori, to generalise concerning the nature of these linkages and impacts.

As with any other products, the costs of production and hence profitability of agricultural commodities are influenced by the prices to be paid for oil. The strength of these effects would depend on the oil intensity of production of the particular commodity concerned, but other things being equal, it might be expected that increases in oil prices would eventually be reflected in higher agricultural commodity prices.

Perhaps the most discussed impact of oil price changes is on the economic growth performance of the oil-importing countries, especially the industrialised countries which also provide major markets for traded agricultural commodities. An increase in oil prices is expected to lead to a slowdown in the rate of economic growth and hence in the demand for all commodities. As a result, commodity stocks rise and prices fall. The impact on economic growth is likely to be more severe for oil-importing developing countries, for the reasons given above, but any knock-on effect on commodity prices would be less pronounced since these countries are generally less significant as commodity importers. It is however possible that the reduction in domestic demand for tradeable commodities might lead to an increase in exportable surpluses, reinforcing downward pressure on prices.

For the oil-exporting countries, the effect of an oil price rise on demand is obviously the reverse of that for oil-importers. Increasing oil revenues stimulate an expansion of import demand for agricultural commodities, which for certain products could conceivably lead to an increase in their price. Oil price variations may at least have an impact on the pattern of trade. Whether a commodity price effect would actually materialise would depend on the importance of the oil-exporter as an importer of a particular commodity, and the magnitude of the income elasticity of import demand. Changes in the volume of imports by certain oil-exporting countries, notably in the Near East and the Area of the former USSR, can be a major source of price variations for certain commodities. In the case of tea, for example, the Russian Federation is the world’s largest importer and Near Eastern markets are also significant. The volume of imports into these markets appears to be highly income elastic, and to have a significant influence on international tea prices in the short-run.

A potential direct link between oil prices and agricultural commodity prices arises where oil-based synthetic products compete with natural products. Agricultural raw materials markets are the most obvious example, where natural fibres and rubber face generalized competition from synthetic alternatives. Of course, substitution is based on the overall competitiveness of the alternative products in a given use, and this involves not only simple price comparisons but also consideration of product characteristics relevant to the intended use. A rather more complex substitution-based linkage with oil prices arises in the case of sugar in Brazil through use of sugar in ethanol production. As oil prices have risen, increasing amounts of sugar have been diverted for ethanol, and so there might be upward pressure on domestic sugar prices. However, whether this would spill over into an impact on world sugar prices would depend on the supply response of Brazilian sugar. It is possible that this might be asymmetric, with rising oil and sugar prices leading to an expansion of productive capacity which would not be completely reversed at least in the short-run when prices fall.

The overall impact, if any, of an oil price change on agricultural commodity prices would depend on the balance between these various channels of influence. Effects arising through possibilities of technical substitution of natural for synthetic products, or through the costs of commodity production would be expected to be positive. The influence on commodity demand via income changes is less clear. In general terms, changes in the level of economic activity as a result of oil price changes would lead to agricultural commodity prices moving in the opposite direction to oil prices. However, in specific markets, namely the oil-exporting countries, certain agricultural commodity prices might move in the same direction. Whether this latter effect would outweigh the former in influencing international prices would depend upon the importance of the oil-exporting countries in the world market for the commodity concerned.

Quantifying the impact of oil prices: some preliminary empirical evidence

The previous section outlined possible channels through which changes in oil prices might impact upon agricultural commodity prices. However, it is an empirical question whether these linkages exist in practice, and if they do how significant they might be. Given the diversity of the possible linkages it is likely to be difficult to obtain unequivocal results in most cases. This section discusses some results from a preliminary econometric analysis. Further technical detail and a full set of results are available on request from the Raw Materials, Tropical and Horticultural Products Service in the Commodities and Trade Division of FAO. The analysis focuses on fibres where oil price changes might be expected a priori to have the most direct effect through changing the relative prices of the natural and synthetic products.

The analysis seeks to establish whether there are statistically significant relationships between oil prices and fibre prices[9]. Two econometric approaches are used: the first is an application of cointegration analysis to test for the existence of any stable long-run equilibrium relationships between oil and fibre prices; the second is a test of whether oil prices add explanatory power to structural econometric models of the determination of international fibre prices.

Cointegration analysis focuses on possible long-run relationships between the price series for oil and the various fibres. Specifically, it tests whether there is some stable long-run or equilibrium relationship between the prices which will tend to be restored following any deviations from it, and analyses the adjustment process towards restoration of the long-run relationship. In statistical terms, the existence of such a relationship would be revealed by the satisfaction of two conditions. The first is that the price series concerned should have similar properties, such as similar trend behaviour. The second is that the price series should move together through time with no tendency to depart in any systematic way from their long-run relationship. Various statistical testing procedures are available in relation to each of these conditions. However, in many instances these tests have low power and can give inconclusive or even conflicting results.

The results of the cointegration analysis are mixed. All the individual price series appear to share the same basic statistical properties in terms of trend behaviour so the first condition appears to be satisfied. However, results of tests for the existence of long-run relationships between prices are conflicting, depending upon the tests applied and whether quarterly or monthly data are used. The Johansen test procedure, which focuses on estimates of the long-run relationships between oil and fibre prices, indicates no such long-run relationships, and hence no price transmission existing between oil prices and each of the fibre prices, including polypropylene. However, an alternative test procedure which focuses on analysing how fibre prices adjust to oil price changes so as to restore a long-run relationship between them indicates that fibre prices do adjust to oil prices in this way. Using quarterly data, this result holds for each of the fibres considered. The adjustment coefficient, which measures how fibre prices adjust to restore the long-run relationship with oil prices, are highly statistically significant, although they are small in magnitude indicating that adjustment is relatively slow, and that oil price changes are not fully propagated to fibre prices. However, repeating this analysis using monthly data, the results indicate that only cotton prices adjust to oil prices in this way. Again, while a long-run relationship appears to hold, there appears to be only partial transmission from oil to cotton prices and the adjustment of cotton prices to oil price changes is slow.

The alternative approach to analysing whether oil prices have a significant impact on fibre prices uses simple dynamic econometric models of the determination of fibre prices. Such models are widely-used in commodity market analysis. They relate each fibre price to its recent history, and the levels of demand and stocks. These models were estimated for cotton, jute and sisal, since quantity data for polypropylene could not be obtained. The explanatory power of these models is acceptable and the estimated coefficients are statistically significant. A test of whether oil prices also have a role in determining fibre prices can be made by adding oil prices to the models, and then testing whether the estimated oil price coefficient is statistically significantly different from zero. If so, this implies that oil prices do make a significant net contribution to explaining movements in fibre prices. In the case of cotton and jute, it appears that oil prices do not provide any significant improvement in the explanatory power of the models. However, according to these results, they do appear to make a significant contribution to the determination of sisal prices.

Do oil prices affect agricultural commodity prices?

While in theory there are a number of economic relationships through which oil price changes might impact upon agricultural commodity prices, the empirical analysis gives only limited support to the view that any such impacts might be significant. The econometric analysis undertaken is, of course, preliminary, and confined to a small number and range of commodities. Nevertheless, it is in relation to natural fibres that some of the most direct and perhaps consequently some of the strongest effects might be expected. Some significant effects are indicated, but the evidence is not consistent. Overall, the results do not support the view that oil prices are a regular and major influence on fibre prices. A number of reasons might be put forward to account for this.

Key to the hypothesised link between oil prices and fibre prices is the assumption that oil price changes lead to changes in synthetic fibre prices, and hence in their relative prices vis-à-vis natural fibres. However, there does not appear to be a strong stable relationship between oil prices and polypropylene prices, for example. This may reflect competitive conditions in the industry which mean that oil price changes are not fully reflected in polypropylene prices. While substitution in use provides a channel through which changes in oil prices may impact on agricultural commodity prices, the significance of any such impacts which change the relative prices of the natural and synthetic products is not clear a priori, since the wider aspects of competitiveness need to be taken into consideration. The latter may have more of an impact on the longer-term trends in substitution. In the case of jute, for example, the introduction of polypropylene sacks and bags made substantial inroads into the market share of jute sacks and bags not only because the polypropylene product was cheaper, but also because in many uses it was seen as offering superior product performance. Polypropylene is also challenging jute for market share in carpet backing, although it is not necessarily a cheaper alternative. Furthermore, the extent of any substitution, whether in response to relative price changes or a re-evaluation of relative technical performance may be limited by the technical and economic possibilities for switching between alternatives, and the associated adjustment costs.

It may also be that the various possible effects of oil price changes may be offsetting so that any positive effects arising from substitution may be offset by negative effects arising from the influence of oil prices on overall commodity demand. However, as noted above, downturns in economic activity in the industrialised countries as a consequence of oil price hikes are nowadays less severe than in the past. Such generalized demand-side effects might therefore be limited, especially against the background of longer-term commodity price trends resulting from growth in commodity production and stocks, substitution by synthetic alternatives, and simple consumer preference shifts. The more generalized potential impacts of oil prices on agricultural commodity prices operating through the demand for those commodities would presumably be more diffuse. For certain commodities where oil-exporting countries are significant importers in terms of market share the impact on demand and prices of changes in oil revenues might well be significant, and certainly this would be worth quantitative investigation. However, the preliminary analysis of fibre markets presented here suggests that a statistically significant link between oil prices and fibre prices cannot be unequivocably established, and that if such links do exist they are weak.

Tariff peaks in agricultural markets and tariff cutting formulae

Introduction

Under the market access provisions of the Agreement on Agriculture (AoA), WTO members agreed to convert their non-tariff import barriers into equivalent tariffs. This was done through a process known as “tariffication”[10]. In addition, developing countries were given the option of adopting ceiling bindings for tariffs that were not previously bound. The Uruguay Round (UR) reduction commitments established that developed countries would reduce their tariffs, including those resulting from tariffication, on a simple average basis of 36 percent (24 percent for developing countries) with minimum cuts of 15 percent (10 percent for developing countries) per tariff line implemented in equal annual instalments up to year 2001 (year 2006 for developing countries). No reduction requirements were established for the least developed countries.

This paper analyses the current market access situation in agricultural markets. Specifically, it identifies those commodity groups in the food and agricultural sector for which tariff peaks prevail, and examines how the implementation of alternative tariff cutting formulae could further affect those tariffs. The study uses data available from the Agricultural Market Access Database (AMAD)[11], and covers the 1995-98 period. For some countries, where available, 1999 data are also taken into account. The countries included in the AMAD database are the developed and developing members of the World Trade Organization (WTO) that scheduled tariff rate quotas (TRQs) and those additional developing members that listed tariff reduction commitments on a tariff line basis in their Uruguay Round schedules.

The incidence of tariff peaks

Tariff peaks are defined here as rates above 20 percent ad valorem[12]. Table 3.1 shows that high bound and applied tariffs are still common in global agricultural markets, even after the implementation of the UR AoA commitments. Moreover, the frequency of heavily protected tariff lines, bound and applied, is still significant for many commodity groupings. In the developed economies the highest tariff peaks are in the oilseeds, dairy, meat and wheat sectors. In the case of developing countries, the most prominent peak levels are in the meat, oilseeds and coarse grains sectors. It should be recalled, however, that this analysis on the basis of most favoured nation (MFN) tariffs does not take account of preferential market access that is frequently extended to developing or least developed countries.

Table 3.1. Tariff Peaks in selected Developed and Developing Countries, 1995-98 (percentages)

Commodity
Group

Average Peak Tariff

Average Number of Tariff Lines above the 20% Peak

Percentage of Countries with Tariff Peaks

Bound Rate

Applied Rate



Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Bovine

192

83

123

49

18

13

65

60

Ovine

134

81

111

69

20

13

45

40

Pork

168

73

100

44

31

21

60

50

Poultry

140

73

129

50

34

30

65

55

Other meat

90

53

49

37

9

8

45

45

Dairy

153

79

119

35

69

35

75

70

Coarse Grains

124

81

93

44

18

22

60

55

Rice

123

61

71

35

16

7

50

60

Wheat

139

75

127

41

11

11

60

60

Oilmeals

31

68

23

41

4

5

15

25

Oilseeds

208

77

179

52

19

9

50

30

Vegetable Oils

107

57

90

39

15

32

70

50

Sugar

83

70

75

36

14

11

70

70

Fruits & Vegetables

120

51

110

33

161

176

70

55

Cocoa

117

43

86

26

15

7

60

60

Coffee

70

54

20

32

1

5

15

40

Tea

95

77

23

50

2

3

15

40

Tobacco

70

84

61

56

8

10

50

55

Cotton

30

62

29

45

3

2

10

5

Hard Fibres

55

100

53

32

3

3

10

5

Hides & Skins

48

58

32

36

15

7

10

15

Source: AMAD and FAO. Includes only countries in the AMAD database
In general, applied peak tariffs are significantly lower than bound peak tariffs for both developed and developing countries. For some commodities, the bulk of trade takes place under relatively low applied tariff levels. A detailed examination of trade conditions for each commodity grouping is beyond the scope of this paper, however, since the objective of the study is to highlight tariff peak levels in the different commodity groupings that could be subject to reductions in further trade negotiations.

The tariffication process under the UR, which disciplined the use of non-tariff measures, often resulted in higher bound tariffs than those prevailing before the Round. This fact has allowed for the persistence and even the increase of peak applied tariffs. In the developed economies, the application of the special agricultural safeguard clause has also led to additional duties in the beef, sugar, poultry and dairy sectors (UNCTAD, 2000).

Tariff cutting formulae and tariff profiles

A variety of tariff-cutting formulae have been proposed over successive rounds of multilateral trade negotiations. This section examines the potential effects of applying alternative tariff-cutting formulae to the identified bound peak levels. The objective is to assess how application of alternative formulae would affect the tariff profile for agricultural products, including the prevalence of peak tariffs. The tariff-cutting formulae utilized in this analysis were selected on the basis of tariff reduction proposals that were presented in the previous rounds of GATT negotiations, and that have already been compiled and analysed in a systematic way (Wainio et al, 2000; Laird, 1999[13]). Although not all of these formulae have been put into practice, some of them, such as the Swiss formula, have been subject to intensive debate in academic and professional circles during the post UR period.

The various alternative tariff-cutting formulae which have been discussed or applied in the context of previous trade rounds are defined in Table 3.2. These include: average linear tariff cuts as agreed in the AoA (36 percent for developed countries and 24 percent for developing countries)[14]; 50 percent linear cuts as applied to industrial goods in the Kennedy Round; four formulae proposed during the Tokyo Round, including 40 percent linear cuts; and the compromise Swiss formula finally adopted in that Round. Harmonising formulae, such as the Swiss formula, impose proportionately higher cuts on higher tariffs. However, their effect depends critically on the value of the formula coefficient - the maximum tariff which is to be permitted, and this would obviously be subject to negotiation in any actual trade round. In the Tokyo Round this was set at 16 percent, but only for industrial goods.

Table 3.2. Tariff Cutting Formulae (t0 is the original tariff and t1 the revised)

Cutting Formulae

GATT Round

Mathematical Expression

UR linear cut

Uruguay

t1 = t0 * (1 - 0.36) or t1 = t0 * (1 - 0.24)

50% linear cut

Kennedy

t1 = t0 * (0.5)

40% linear cut

Tokyo

t1 = t0 * (1- 0.4)

Linear cuts plus selective one step reduction

Tokyo

If t0 > 40%, t1 = 20%; otherwise, t1 = t0 * (0.5)

Iterative cuts

Tokyo

If t0 > 50%, t1 = 0.5 (1 - 0.5); applied three times
Otherwise, t1 = t0 (1 - t0); applied three times

Linear cuts with harmonization

Tokyo

t1 = t0 * (0.3) + 3.5%

Swiss formula

Tokyo

t1 = (a* t0)/(a + t0); a is a parameter = 0.16

Source: USDA and S. Laird.
Figure 3.6 shows how linear and Swiss methods compare in terms of tariff reductions. For initial tariffs below 25 percent, the Swiss formula with a coefficient of 0.5 gives about the same result as the linear 36 percent cut of the AoA. For higher initial tariffs, however, the Swiss formula produces substantially larger cuts, so it would be more effective in reducing tariff peaks and escalation, without sharply reducing already-low tariffs.

Figure 3.6. Examples of tariff reductions resulting from two tariff cutting formulae

Although in the on-going negotiation process no formal proposals have been adopted so far, current negotiating proposals are similar to the ones simulated in this study. Current tariff cutting proposals even include requests-and-offer tariff cuts on product by product and case-by-case basis (e.g. Switzerland, Japan, Norway) and zero-for-zero sectoral negotiations for selected products (e.g. Canada, US). However, most reduction proposals rely on formulae that are applied over a broad range of products. These tariff cutting formulae vary from a replication of the UR tariff cut modalities (e.g. EC, Poland) to the application of harmonising formulae to eliminate tariff peaks and escalation (e.g. Cairns Group, CARICOM, African Group).

Figures are given in Table 3.3 for the tariff rates that would result after the application of each of the formulae listed in Table 3.2. The first three columns show the effects of linear tariff cuts of 36 percent or 24 percent (Uruguay Round), 50 percent (Kennedy Round), and 40 percent (Tokyo Round). The final column of Table 3.3 shows the effects of application of the Swiss formula with a coefficient (maximum permitted tariff) of 16 percent as agreed in the Tokyo Round.

Perhaps the most notable finding of this analysis is that a repetition of the cuts implemented under the UR would leave significant tariff peaks remaining in all commodity groups, both for the developed and for the developing countries. The application of more aggressive linear cuts, such as those proposed for industrial goods in the Kennedy (50 percent) and the Tokyo (40 percent) Rounds, would lead to lower protection levels, although significant bound tariff peaks could still persist in most agricultural sectors. This suggests that linear cuts, even at higher levels than those implemented in the UR, would not eliminate tariff peaks. Only the application of harmonizing formulae, such as the iterative cuts formula or the Swiss formula, would effectively reduce tariff peaks, both for the developed and the developing countries.

However, it should be noted that the results of the application of the Swiss formula depend on the formula coefficient, which would need to be defined. As noted above, the results in Table 3.3 are based on the Tokyo Round application of the Swiss formula, with the coefficient set at 0.16, so all tariffs above 16 percent are driven below this level. This is perhaps an extreme example in the case of agricultural products. However, this example illustrates that such a formula is well suited for eliminating tariff peaks, as they are defined in here, and that it compresses tariffs within a narrow range without necessarily imposing deep cuts in tariffs below the formula coefficient. Therefore the results presented here reinforce those proposals that aim to reduce tariff peaks, showing that the application of harmonising formulae is the most effective way to achieve that objective.

Table 3.3. Resulting tariffs after the Application of Tariff Cutting Formulae to Selected Commodity Groups with Peak Tariffs in the Developed and Developing Countries (average percentage)

Commodity Group

Tariff Cutting Formulae

UR formula

Kennedy Round formula

40% linear cuts

Linear cuts plus one step reduction

Iterative cuts

Linear cuts with harmonization

Swiss formula

Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Developed Countries

Developing Countries

Bovine

123

63

96

42

103

50

19

18

15

15

61

29

13

12

Pork

107

55

84

36

86

44

19

18

15

15

54

25

13

12

Poultry

89

55

70

36

73

44

18

18

15

15

45

25

13

12

Dairy

100

60

78

40

86

48

20

19

15

15

50

27

14

13

Ovine

86

61

67

40

80

49

18

16

15

14

44

28

13

12

Other meat

58

41

45

27

54

32

18

17

14

14

30

20

12

12

Coarse Grains

79

61

62

40

74

48

19

19

15

15

41

28

13

13

Rice

79

47

61

31

74

37

19

18

15

15

40

22

13

12

Wheat

89

57

69

37

83

45

19

18

15

15

45

26

14

12

Oilmeals

20

52

15

34

18

41

15

19

14

15

13

24

10

13

Oilseeds

133

59

104

39

125

46

20

19

15

15

66

27

14

12

Vegetable Oils

69

43

54

28

64

34

18

17

15

14

36

20

12

12

Sugar

53

53

41

35

50

42

19

18

15

15

28

24

13

12

Fruits & Vegetables

77

39

60

25

72

30

19

18

15

14

39

19

13

12

Cocoa

75

33

58

22

70

26

18

16

15

14

39

16

13

11

Coffee

44

41

35

27

42

32

15

16

13

14

24

20

11

11

Tea

61

58

48

38

57

46

15

17

13

14

32

27

12

12

Tobacco

45

61

35

40

42

48

18

16

15

14

25

28

12

12

Cotton

19

47

15

31

17

37

15

16

14

14

12

22

10

12

Hard Fibres

35

76

27

50

32

60

20

20

15

15

20

34

12

14

Hides & Skins

31

44

24

29

29

35

20

18

15

14

28

21

12

12

Includes only countries in the AMAD database of which 30 are developing and 16 are developed.
All tariffs in ad-valorem equivalent

Source: AMAD and FAO.

References

Laird, S. (1999). “Multilateral Approaches to Market Access Negotiations”, in Rodriguez, M., P. Low and B. Kotschwar, eds. Trade Rules in the Making Challenges in Regional and Multilateral Negotiation, Organization of American States, Brookings Institution Press, Washington DC, 1999.

UNCTAD (2000). The Post-Uruguay Round Tariff Environment for Developing Country Exports: Tariff Peaks and Tariff Escalation, (TD/B/COM.1/14/Rev.1), January 2000, UNCTAD, Geneva.

Wainio, J., P. Gibson, and D. Whitley (2000). Evaluating Alternative Formulas for Reducing Agricultural Tariffs, Economic Research Service, USDA, Washington DC, 2000.

Recent trends in deficits and surpluses in basic food commodities in Africa

Trade can be an important contributor to economic growth and food security in developing countries. In Africa, most countries rely on exports of primary commodities such as coffee, cocoa, cotton, tobacco, tea, copper, etc, to earn foreign exchange with which to finance development programmes, as well as to import foods they do not produce or to cover shortfalls in domestic food production. However, experience has shown that relying on one or two primary commodities for export, as most do, is highly risky because world commodity markets are prone to sharp price swings. One way of minimizing the impact of price instability is to diversify the range of exports and also to find new markets. Intra-African trade is relatively very small compared to the region’s trade with the rest of the world. In 2000, intra-African trade grossed $11 billion compared to $145 billion from trade with the rest of the world, or a share of only 7.6 percent. Intra-regional trade can reinforce the economic complementarities among neighbouring countries and stimulate additional growth both in agriculture and related sectors. One potential area where intra-African trade could be promoted is trade in food commodities such as cereals, edible oils, livestock and livestock products.

The purpose of this note is to examine recent trends in surpluses and deficits in major, readily tradable food commodities in Africa, sub-region by sub-region, in order to explore potentials for intra-African trade. Trends in imports of rice and wheat, for which Africa is a net importer are examined. Trends in imports of other food commodities such as vegetable oils, animal products and sugar are also briefly summarized as well.

Deficits/surpluses in coarse grains[15] in 1999/2000 and 2000/2001

Maize and to a lesser extent sorghum and millet are the most important food crops traded in Africa. Root and tuber crops and plantains/bananas, though important staples in some countries, are hardly traded internationally (including within Africa) due to their high transport cost relative to their unit value. Table 3.4 presents estimates of cereal surpluses and deficits in 1999/00 and 2000/01, the latest two marketing years for which full data are available. In 1999/00, all the sub-regions were in deficit, whilst in 2000/01 southern Africa showed a surplus of 651 000 tonnes, accounted for by only three countries, namely South Africa, Malawi and Zambia. However, in marketing year 2001/02[16], this sub-region is likely to be in deficit, as grain production has declined significantly in most countries, including the sub-region’s leading grain producer and exporter, South Africa. North Africa (a non-producer) has the largest deficit, while Central Africa (a minor producer, dependent mainly on roots and tubers) has the smallest. Whereas a number of countries posted a surplus in 1999/00 (Ethiopia, Sudan, Uganda in eastern Africa; Benin, Chad, Côte d’Ivoire, Ghana, Mali, Mauritania, Nigeria, Togo in western Africa; Madagascar, Malawi, Mozambique in southern Africa), only three countries in the whole African Region, namely Malawi, South Africa and Zambia, had a surplus in 2000/01.

In eastern Africa, the deficit increased by 70 percent from around 1.4 million tonnes in 1999/00 to 2.4 million tonnes in 2000/01, reflecting mainly the impact of a severe drought. Kenya, among the hardest hit, accounts for the largest share, 56 percent, of the total deficit in 2000/01.

Table 3.4. Africa: Coarse grains[17] surpluses/deficits in 1999/00-2000/01 (‘000 tonnes)


1999/00

2000/01


1999/00

2000/01

Northern Africa

-7 661

-9 689

Western Africa

-275

-593


Algeria

-1 501

-1 806


Coastal countries

-5

-166


Egypt

-3 310

-4 220


Benin

25

-3


Libya

-650

-710


Ghana

15

-45


Morocco

-1 600

-2 100


Nigeria

10

-70


Tunisia

-600

-853


Togo

10

-





Côte d’Ivoire



Eastern Africa

-1 425

-2 425


Guinea

5

-8


Ethiopia

153

-70


Liberia

0

-


Sudan

93

-90


Sierra Leone

-10

-10


Uganda

80

-50

Sahelian countries

-60

-30


Burundi

-40

-81


Mali

-135

-427


Comoros

0

-


Chad

50

-


Djibouti

0

-3


Mauritania

18

-15


Eritrea

-140

-90


Gambia

2

-15


Kenya

-800

-1 364


Guinea-Bissau

0

-


Rwanda

-185

-150


Burkina Faso

-5

-15


Somalia

-60

-71


Cape Verde

-15

-80


Seychelles

-6

-6


Niger

-30

-35


Tanzania

-520

-450


Senegal

-70

-230

Southern Africa

-1 003

651

Central Africa

-85

-37


Malawi

400

300


Cameroon

-78

-82


Mozambique

150

-50


Equatorial Guinea

0

-10


Madagascar

5

-30


Gabon

0

-


Angola

-215

-394


Sao Tome

-2

-2


Botswana

-185

-185


Central Afr. Rep.

-2

-2


Lesotho

-155

-190


Congo, Rep. of

-4

-3


Namibia

-84

-60


Congo, Dem. Rep.

-10

-5


South Africa

-77

1 250


-60

-60


Swaziland

-22

-40





Zambia

-370

50





Zimbabwe

-450

-





Trends in imports and exports of maize

In most of Africa, trade in coarse grains is almost synonymous with trade in maize. Although some trade in sorghum and millet takes place among the Sahelian countries, it is insignificant on Africa-wide scale. In eastern Africa, Sudan is the only major producer of sorghum and exports significant amounts in good years, mainly to the Near East. Thus, only trade in maize is reviewed in detail. The graphs below show trends in maize imports and exports during the period 1994/95-2000/01.

Imports and exports 1994/95-2000/01

Fig.1 - North Africa Maize Imports & Exports, 1994/95-2000/01

Fig.2 - North Africa Wheat & Rice Imports, 1994/95-2000/01

Fig.3 - East Africa Maize Imports & Exports, 1994/95-2000/01

Fig.4 - East Africa Wheat & Rice Imports, 1994/95-2000/01

Fig.5 - Western Africa Maize Imports & Exports, 1994/95-2000/01

Fig.6 - Western Africa Wheat & Rice Imports, 1994/95-2000/01

Fig.7 - Central Africa Maize Imports & Exports, 1994/95-2000/01

Fig.8 - Central Africa Wheat & Rice Imports, 1994/95-2000/01

Fig.9 - Southern Africa Maize Imports & Exports, 1994/95-2000/01

Fig.10 - Southern Africa Wheat & Rice Imports, 1994/95-2000/01

Maize Imports

North Africa is the largest importer of maize and consignments show a strong upward trend (Fig.1). Imports averaged over 5 million tonnes annually over the 7-year period (1994/95-2000/01). It would seem that North Africa could be a major market for sub-Saharan African maize, if large exportable surpluses were available and were competitive on the world market.

In eastern Africa, a rising trend in maize imports is evident (Fig. 3). These imports are largely driven by Kenya, which has imported an average of 745 000 tonnes per year during the 7-year period, out of a sub-regional average of 1.33 million tonnes. The dip in imports in 1998/99 reflected Kenya’s bumper harvest that year. Tanzania is a distant second (average 224 000 tonnes), followed by Rwanda (average: 169 000 tonnes). In western Africa, maize imports appear to have stabilized at around 300 000 tonnes annually since 1998/99 (Fig. 5). Sahelian countries account for then bulk of the imports (7-year average: 240 000 tonnes compared to 150 000 tonnes for coastal countries). This is rather surprising as sorghum and millet production in the Sahel has been at record to above-average levels since 1996. In Central Africa (Fig. 7), maize imports are on the increase, but the quantities involved are relatively small. In southern Africa (Fig. 9), the pattern is less clear, but largely reflects seasonal rainfall behaviour. For example, the high maize imports in 1995/96 reflected the impact of the severe drought in 1994/95. As already indicated, the sharp falls in maize production in various countries in 2000/01 are likely to result in a significant increase in the sub-region’s maize imports in the 2001/02 marketing year.

Maize Exports

In eastern Africa, the trend is downward (Fig. 3), exports having fallen from a peak of nearly 1 million tonnes in 1995/96 to an annual average of around 280 000 tonnes since 1997/98. Only Uganda has consistently exported maize over the period, although the quantities have been declining. Maize exports are mainly within the sub-region, but marketing problems arise for surplus producers when their neighbours become self-sufficient in good years, as the tendency is to ban imports. In western Africa, a downward trend is also apparent (Fig. 5), although over the last three years the average has hovered around 125 000 tonnes. The main exporters (albeit with relatively small quantities) are Nigeria, Benin and Mali. In central Africa, only Cameroon exports small quantities of maize, which have averaged about 10 000 tonnes per annum over the 7-year period. In southern Africa, the high level of maize exports (nearly 5 million tonnes) in 1994/95 was followed by a sharp drop (to about 400 000 tonnes) in 1995/96 due to drought. A modest recovery was posted in 1996/97, after which a downward trend was evident up to 1999/00. This downward trend is set to resume in 2001/02 after a relatively small increase in 2000/01, mainly due to mid-season dry spells that affected crops in several countries. The main exporters have been South Africa and Zimbabwe (the latter up to 1999/00).

Trends in wheat and rice imports

Figs. 2, 4, 6, 8 and 10 show trends in wheat and rice imports. All African countries are net importers of wheat and, with the exception of Egypt, also of rice. Wheat imports appear to be growing fastest in eastern Africa, having almost tripled between 1995/96 and 1999/00. In western Africa, rice imports have overtaken wheat imports since 1998/99 (Fig. 6).

Trends in deficits/surpluses in other traded food commodities

The other major food commodities traded extensively in Africa include edible oils, livestock products (meat and dairy) and sugar.

Edible Oils

Africa as a whole is a net importer of edible oils. The deficits have increased continuously over the 1990s, nearly doubling from 2.2 million tonnes in 1991 to about 3.8 million tonnes in 2000. The main deficit countries are located in northern Africa which, as a region, accounts for nearly 60 percent of the total deficit. However, Ethiopia, Kenya, Tanzania, South Africa, Nigeria and Senegal from the sub-Saharan region are also important importers, despite the fact that some of them are significant producers. The deficits vary considerably from year to year depending on domestic production and other factors. The main oils imported by Africa are (in order of importance) palm oil, soybean oil and sunflower oil.

The only potential net exporting sub-regions are western and central Africa, although west Africa seems to have turned into a net importing region since the mid-1990s, while central Africa's net exporting position depends on a single exporter, Cameroon (in palm oil).

Western Africa's main net exporters are Côte d'Ivoire (coconut oil, palm oil, palm kernel oil) and Ghana (palm oil). Côte d'Ivoire's surplus fell steadily during the mid-1990s but has stabilised in recent years. Minor net exporters include Mali (groundnut oil) and Benin (palm oil, palm kernel oil). Senegal used to be a net exporter, but became a net importer in the early 1990s.

Dairy Products

Africa as a whole, its sub-regions as well as individual countries, has been consistently in deficit in dairy products over the past decade (averaging around 5.0 million tonnes per annum in recent years). The deficit is equivalent to 20 percent of regional milk production. North Africa accounts for approximately 50 percent of the deficit, with Algeria alone leading the way with nearly 40 percent of the total for Africa. In sub-Saharan Africa, the principal importing country is Nigeria, accounting for 20 percent of the deficit for Africa as a whole. Elsewhere in the region, Egypt, Libya, Morocco, Tunisia, Senegal, Côte d’Ivoire, Mauritius and Botswana have all registered annual deficits of over 100 000 tonnes in the past few years.

Meat Products

There is a persistent and growing meat deficit in Africa, which increased from 370 000 tonnes in the early 1990s to an estimated 655 000 tonnes in 2000, with the contribution of imports in meeting overall consumption increasing from 5 percent over the period to 7 percent. Meanwhile, despite annual average meat output gains of 2 percent over the decade and 4 percent growth in meat imports, per caput meat consumption continues to deteriorate, inching downward over the decade from 14.6 kg/caput at the beginning to an estimated 14 kg/caput in 2000. While some countries in the region are important exporters of live animals, the prevalence of animal diseases has impeded such trade, with the region as a whole turning into a net cattle importer over the course of the decade. Live sheep trade continues to provide net foreign exchange earnings; however, growth in shipments from the region’s largest exporters in the Horn of Africa has been constrained by disease outbreaks of Rift Valley Fever.

While meat exports expanded only slightly over the decade, imports grew much more, mainly in response to growing demand in South Africa and Egypt, two of the region’s largest importers. In fact, meat deficits in these two countries account for nearly two-thirds of the growing regional deficit. There are few examples of countries, apart from the traditional meat exporting countries of Zimbabwe and the Sudan, experiencing emerging surpluses recently. Other important meat exporting countries, such as Botwana and Namibia witnessed an erosion in their surplus position as drought reduced livestock production and exports. Although there appears to be some scope for promoting intra-trade in the continent, the special nature and infrastructure requirements of meat products, stemming from their perishability, create constraints that hamper rapid development of trade in these products. Potential exists for expanding live animal trade, especially from the Horn of Africa into the Middle East; however, recurring disease outbreaks at present limit such an expansion.

Sugar

Africa is net importer of sugar, with deficits averaging almost 2 million tonnes per year during the 1990s and rising since 1997 to over 2 million tonnes. Only eight of the 53 African countries were net surplus producers (South Africa, Mauritius, Swaziland, Zimbabwe, Sudan, Zambia, Malawi and the Republic of Congo), with much of this surplus exported as raw sugar under preferential trade agreements. The five largest deficit importing countries were Nigeria, Egypt, Morocco, Algeria and Tunisia, all of which are major importers of white refined sugar. Trade statistics indicate that while 22 African countries have exported sugar, only seven of these were in a net surplus position. Currently, there is a fair level of trade among African countries, primarily between neighbouring countries where sugar trade flows from surplus to deficit regions.

An issue concerning African sugar trade in the context of intra-trade is trade diversion created by preferential access opportunities to African exports. Preferential access to the EC and United States markets mean that exports to those markets receive much higher prices than to free markets, including to Africa. It seems to be a common practice for many to export sugar to the EC and United States markets under preferential terms and to import sugar at relatively lower world market prices, including from Africa. In fact, many of the largest net deficit African countries import white refined sugar from the EC, taking advantage of export restitution, at the cost of both African and non-African sugar.

Conclusion

With the exception of edible oils, meat and sugar, of which a handful of countries are net exporters, Africa is largely a food-deficit region, particularly in foodgrains, and is increasingly relying on food imports. There would be considerable potential for intra-African trade, but exportable surpluses are scarce. For coarse grains, which are the major cereals produced in Africa, North Africa is potentially a major market for sub-Saharan Africa, if large enough surpluses were available and competitive on world markets. The main constraints to increased intra-African trade include low farm productivity, poor transport infrastructure, low purchasing power and trade barriers such as bans on food imports when countries have bumper harvests. While trade issues are being addressed within the framework of regional economic groupings such as COMESA, SADC and ECOWAS, increased investment in infrastructure and agricultural research remains the main challenge for national governments.

Impact of the Uruguay Round Agreements of relevance to the agricultural sector: Winners and losers

Introduction

The Uruguay Round was a turning point in the evolution of agricultural policy. For the first time, a large majority of countries agreed a set of principles and disciplines to reduce the trade distortions caused by agricultural policies. This note summarises the main accomplishments of the Agreement on Agriculture (AoA) and the other Uruguay Round Agreements of relevance to agriculture and food security issues, including the Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (SPS), the Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT) and the Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) and the Decision Concerning the Possible Negative Effects of the Reform Programme on Least-Developed and Net Food-Importing Developing Countries. It identifies areas where further reforms are needed and, after six years of implementation, explores the evidence regarding winners and losers in the reform process.

Agreement on Agriculture

The Agreement on Agriculture (AoA) brought national agricultural policies under multilateral rules and disciplines, with the long-term objective of establishing “a fair and market-oriented agricultural trading system... through substantial progressive reductions in agricultural support and protection.” The AoA includes specific binding commitments by WTO members to improve market access and to reduce production- and trade-distorting domestic support and export subsidies.

A basic motivation for the AoA was the need to reduce surplus production caused by rising levels of support and protection in a number of developed countries during the 1980s and early 1990s. This was known as a period of “disarray” in global commodity markets as some of the largest agricultural exporters competed on the basis their governments’ ability to subsidise production and exports while limiting access to their markets for products from lower-cost suppliers. By agreeing to cap and reduce these subsidy levels and import barriers, the developed countries hoped to bring an end to the “subsidy wars” that were draining their national budgets and driving down world commodity prices.

The vast majority of developing countries, on the other hand, entered the Uruguay Round with under-developed agricultural sectors and insufficient resources to raise productivity and output in line with their food needs and production potential. Their farmers were forced to compete with the treasuries of the world’s richest countries in export markets and in their home markets. While consumers in developing countries could be said to “benefit” from the availability of subsidised supplies, the situation was unstable and unsustainable.

Prior to implementation of the AoA most studies of the impact on world markets and trade predicted trade gains for developing country exporters and slightly higher and more stable real world commodity prices. Subsequent analyses based on actual trade developments, however, could not distinguish between the impacts of specific policy changes resulting from the AoA and other factors having an impact on trade, such as macroeconomic shocks, weather-induced supply-side variations, civil strife etc. In this regard, it is important to keep in mind the counter-factual problem: What would have happened to agricultural policies and global markets in the absence of the Agreement?

Policy Impact

· Domestic Support to Agriculture

- Commitments for the reduction of domestic supports: The Agreement categorised domestic support policies according to their potential to distort production and trade, and capped and reduced measures that were considered to cause distortions. These are known as the “Amber Box” policies.

- Reformulation of agricultural supports: Many developed countries changed their agricultural policies in significant ways in anticipation of and following the implementation of the AoA. For example, the EU, the United States and Canada have all moved away - in varying degrees - from market price supports that tend to encourage excess production towards direct income payments and other measures that are less distorting, although not necessarily completely production- and trade-neutral. Figure 3.7 illustrates the shift to less-distorting “Green Box” supports.

- Imbalances in support limits: The upper limits agreed on domestic support were based on the actual level of “distorting” support provided by each country during the 1986-88 base period. For countries that reported little or no distorting supports, a de minimis level of support was set as the cap (5 percent of the value of production for developed countries; 10 percent for developing countries). Because developing countries provided little in the way of distorting domestic support prior to the Agreement, they are now prohibited from exceeding the de minimis level. Since the caps on most developed countries are higher than the de minimis level, it has created an imbalance in the rules regarding domestic support.

- Domestic support in developed countries remains high despite the disciplines agreed in the AoA. The latest figures from the WTO show that the total of Green and Amber box supports in the OECD countries was higher in 1996 in nominal terms than during the base period. More recent data from the OECD, shows that total transfers to agriculture in these countries amounted to $327 billion in 2000, compared with $298 billion in 1986-88, and exceeded the value of world trade in agricultural products[18].

Figure 3.7. Composition of green and amber box outlays in OECD countries

· Export Subsidies

- Commitments on export subsidies: Subsidy levels were capped and reduced both in terms of value and volume. Countries that did not subsidise exports during the base period were prohibited from doing so, except for certain exceptions agreed for developing countries.

- Export subsidies have been reduced somewhat on several products, but they remain high, particularly for meat and dairy products as well as cereals. Export subsidies not only distort competition on global markets but also destabilise world prices. Countries tend to use subsidies more when world prices are low, thus further depressing prices, but subsidises tend to fall when world prices are high, just at the time when importing countries might be said to “benefit” from subsidised supplies.

· Market access
- Commitments on tariffs: Countries agreed to replace their non-tariff import barriers with bound tariffs and, in many cases, to reduce these tariffs. This was an important achievement, because tariffs are more transparent and predictable than non-tariff barriers, and they allow producers and consumers to receive and react to world price signals.

- Agricultural tariffs remain high and complex despite these improvements, especially for temperate-zone products (horticulture, sugar, cereals, dairy products and meat). There is a high degree of variance in agricultural tariffs both within and between individual countries, and tariff escalation (higher tariffs on more processed products, which gives greater protection to the processing industry of the importing country) still prevails in several important product chains (e.g. coffee, cocoa, oilseeds, vegetables, fruit and nuts and hides and skins).

- Tariff rate quotas were created to ease the process of converting non-tariff measures to tariffs. Countries that chose to use this mechanism agreed to provide market access at low or zero tariffs for a fixed quantity of product, while additional quantities could be charged a higher tariff. While tariff rate quotas have created some new trading opportunities, a number of implementation issues have arisen. Moreover, only about 60-65 percent of the potential trade under tariff rate quotas has actually occurred.

- Special safeguard (SSG) provisions were made available for countries that converted their non-tariff barriers to tariff-only regimes according to the procedure known as “tariffication”. The SSG allows an importer to increase tariffs above their bound rate in response to a surge in imports or a sharp decline in import prices. Most developing countries did not use the tariffication procedure, choosing instead to follow a simpler procedure for which the SSG was not made available. Most developed countries, in contrast, used the tariffication procedure and reserved the right to use the SSG, typically for temperate zone products such as meat, cereals, fruit and vegetables, oilseeds and oil products and dairy products.

- Actual protection rates in agriculture are still high and market access terms have not improved much. Recent statistics show that nominal protection rates in the OECD countries have declined somewhat but remain high on the whole. Bound tariffs are also high in many developing countries, although their applied rates are generally lower. A number of developing countries have raised their applied tariffs in recent years - within their bound rates - in an effort to protect domestic producers from the disruptive effects of very low world market prices.

· Special and differential treatment
- Two basic types of special and differential treatment in favour of developing countries are embodied in the AoA. The first are transitional measures that provide longer implementation periods and lower reduction commitments, for example on tariff cuts. The second provide exemptions for measures that are disciplined, such as export subsidies to cover the costs of internal freight or input subsidies for low-income resource-poor farmers.

- Developing countries consider the transitional forms of special and differential treatment to be inadequate, and have called for more substantive measures to help them overcome the under-developed nature of their agricultural sectors.

Trade Impact

As noted above, the AoA was expected to generate slightly higher and more stable world prices for agricultural products and to improve the trade prospects of non-subsidising exporters, including many developing countries. Given the relatively small policy changes that have occurred, however, these impacts have been correspondingly small. Furthermore, other market factors have overwhelmed these modest policy changes, making it difficult to see the impacts clearly.

- World market prices: Figure 3.8 illustrates that prices for basic food commodities spiked in the mid-1990s. Although the downward trend for dairy products has been reversed since 1999, the prices of cereals, meat and oilseed products continue to be depressed at levels that have not been seen for nearly two decades. These developments are contrary to the ex ante expectations regarding the impact of AoA, and largely reflect underlying market conditions that have masked the effects of the implementation of AoA. However, as noted above, support and protection to agriculture continue at high levels, shielding producers from world price signals and adding further downward pressure to prices.
Figure 3.8. FAO price indices for major food and feed commodity groups

Agricultural export earnings (excluding fishery and forestry products) increased significantly between 1993 and 1997, for both the developing and developed countries (Figure 3.9). Higher world market prices were a major factor in this growth, particularly in 1995 and 1996, although volumes also increased. The decline in exports after 1997 was largely due to the economic crisis that disrupted demand in a number of developing and transition countries that had been amongst the fastest growing markets for agricultural products in the mid-1990s. It is difficult to draw clear conclusions about the impact of the AoA on aggregate commodity markets, but the export market shares of “non-subsidising” exporters have increased for cereals, milk and beef, for example, suggesting some rebalancing of the world market has occurred.

Figure 3.9. Total agricultural export earnings

The value of total food imports also rose sharply between 1993 and 1997, but declined thereafter (Figure 3.10). Comparing the period immediately before the implementation of the AoA with the period since 1995, food imports increased 44 percent for developing countries (27 percent for the LDCs among them) and 21 percent for developed countries. Import bills have declined since the price spike of the mid-1990s, but appear to have remained on a higher plateau.

Figure 3.10. Total food imports

Marrakesh Decision

The Decision on Measures Concerning the Negative Effects of the Reform Programme on Least-Developed and Net Food-Importing Developing Countries which is an integral part of the results of the Uruguay Round was adopted to address the following concern:

“Ministers recognize that during the reform programme leading to greater liberalization of trade in agriculture, least-developed countries and the net-food importing developing countries may experience negative effects in terms of adequate supplies of basic foodstuffs from external sources on reasonable terms and conditions, including short-term difficulties in financing normal levels of commercial imports of basic foodstuffs”[19].
To deal with this eventuality, the Decision provided for four response mechanisms, i.e., food aid, short-term financing of normal levels of commercial imports, favourable terms on agricultural export credits, and technical and financial assistance to improve agricultural productivity.

To date, the Decision has not been made operationally effective. Implementation has so far been hampered by several factors which include the requirement of undisputed proof of the need for assistance (and whether the need resulted from the reform process under the Uruguay Round) and the variety of instruments called under the Decision to respond to such needs, without precise specification of the respective responsibilities of all concerned. Thus, LDCs and NFIDCs have so far not obtained any benefit from this Decision, even during the pronounced spike in food prices of 1995/1996.

Winners and losers

As noted above, it is difficult to identify winners and losers because of the relatively small policy changes that have occurred and the variety of market and policy impacts that have affected global commodity prices and trade since the AoA began. The central difficulty lies in understanding what would have happened to policies and trade in the absence of the AoA. Some conclusions can be drawn by looking at the changes implied by the AoA, in isolation from the other factors that have influenced markets.

- There have been only small reductions thus far in the levels of production- and trade-distorting support and protection provided by the OECD countries, and in many cases underlying market factors have obscured the effects of these small policy changes. Nevertheless, the AoA has established a framework for the further reduction in distorting supports and protection to agriculture which would be expected to benefit non-subsidised farmers in developing countries and elsewhere.

- Although the food import bills for LIFDCs rose sharply in the first few years of implementation, along with the spike in commodity prices, they have since declined. The Marrakesh Decision recognized that some countries might be adversely affected by the reform process due to higher food prices and import costs.

- Exporters of temperate-zone products have seen some improvement in market access (particularly through TRQ allocations) and some disciplines on domestic support policies and on export subsidies (particularly, dairy products and beef). However, the gains have been limited.

- Exporters under preferential arrangement have experienced erosion of the value of these arrangements as general tariffs have come down. This erosion has been small thus far, but this is an issue of concern for the future as further cuts in general tariffs are implemented. On the other hand those countries that did not enjoy preferential access to major markets have seen a modest benefit.

- Some developing countries have experienced import surges (in some cases due to subsidised exports) in various products, which have reportedly damaged their import-competing sectors. Many developing countries have raised tariffs to protect their producers (within their bound rates) in response to the sharp declines in many commodity prices since the peaks of 1995-96. In the absence of alternative appropriate safeguard measures, some countries have found it difficult to live with a tariff-only regime and many are reluctant to accept further cuts in bound tariff rates.

SPS and TBT Agreements

The SPS and TBT Agreements confirm the right of WTO members to apply measures necessary to protect human, animal and plant life and health. These include the setting of technical regulations and standards governing quality requirements for food, packaging, marking and labelling, and national zoo and phytosanitary measures to protect animal and plant life and health. These Agreements define rules for setting national measures so that they do not unduly restrict traffic and trade. SPS measures must be based on scientific principles and not maintained without sufficient evidence. The SPS and TBT agreements encourage international harmonization through the establishment of international sanitary and phytosanitary standards by, respectively, the Codex Alimentarius, the OIE and the International Plant Protection Convention.

Major challenges faced by many countries, particularly the developing countries and countries with economies in transition, are (1) to meet the sanitary, phytosanitary and technical requirements of importing countries, (2) to provide scientific justification for their own sanitary, phytosanitary and technical measures, and (3) to participate in a meaningful manner in the development and adoption of international standards. The gap in the technical and financial ability of countries to meet such standards is wide.

These countries face an additional challenge when new standards are introduced on risk assessment grounds that are stricter than those currently in place, as the time and resources required to ensure conformity with these standards may be considerable. On the other hand, the risk assessment paradigm applied in the SPS Agreement in particular has had the effect of eliminating out-of-date, ineffective or arbitrary standards that may have provided a false sense of security. The transition to risk-based standard setting has required major changes in legislative, regulatory and administrative practices in most countries, all of which have implied significant cost.

Harmonization of phytosanitary measures, through the establishment of International Standards for Phytosanitary Measures (ISPMs), by the IPPC started only recently. A substantial number of concept ISPMs have been adopted but much work remains to be done, in particular on standards specific to individual pests, plants or plant products. FAO and other international and bilateral agencies have provided for phytosanitary capacity building, but much needs to be done to enable countries to participate fully in international trade and traffic.

With some exceptions, disputes under the SPS and TBT Agreements involving food and agricultural products have not involved developing countries as few of them have standards that are stricter than those established by the international standards-setting bodies and therefore have not been challenged by other WTO Members (the main exceptions have been challenges by the US, Canada and Australia against practices in the Republic of Korea over various measures). Few developing countries (or none at all) have used the formal dispute settlement mechanism and the SPS/TBT Agreements to challenge measures applied by importing countries that are believed to be arbitrary or unjustified[20]. On the other hand, developing countries have been active in the SPS and TBT Committees in raising issues of importance to them with the intention of resolving such issues in the informal or consultative processes of the WTO[21].

The SPS and TBT agreements contain promises of financial and technical assistance for the developing countries. However, translating these promises into concrete action has not yet been achieved. Finally, the level of participation of these countries, in both number and effectiveness, in international standard-setting bodies remains an issue.

TRIPS Agreement

The main aspect of the Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) relevant to agriculture is the requirement to provide protection by intellectual property rights to plant varieties, either by patent or by effective sui generis legislation or a combination of both.

Other related issues, such as the rights of local communities and indigenous peoples over their traditional knowledge and practises, sovereign rights over natural genetic resources, biosafety and food security, which are dealt with by the Convention on Biological Diversity, are, however, not considered in the provisions of the TRIPS Agreement.

Many countries, particularly, the developing countries have been facing two sets of difficulties in this area. On the one hand, many countries lack the scientific capability to innovate as well as the expertise and necessary institutional development to use the IPR system as a tool for development. Although the TRIPS Agreement requires the adoption of legislation incorporating minimum standards, and many countries are in the process of doing so, there are still some, particularly LDCs, which do not yet have appropriate legislation in this area. On the other hand, there is a growing concentration of transnational corporations, particularly in the seed and in biotechnology areas. Access to most protected technologies and products is subject to the terms of licensing agreements dictated by a very small number of enterprises. National expertise is also required to make use of the provisions in TRIPS on compulsory licensing to avoid emergency situations leading to food insecurity, provisions that have been recently successfully used in the medicinal sector, both by South Africa and Canada.

The International Treaty on Plant Genetic Resources for Food and Agriculture was adopted formally in the FAO Conference on 3 November 2001. This is a legally binding instrument which provides for the conservation and sustainable use of PGRFA as well as for the fair and equitable sharing of the benefits arising from their use, in harmony with the Convention on Biological Diversity. It includes a number of issues where cooperation, complementarity and synergy with the WTO in general and TRIPS in particular would be essential. In this regard, the relationship between Article 27.3.b of TRIPS which deals with sui generis intellectual property rights systems for plant varieties and Article 8 of the new International Treaty on Farmers’ Rights is important.

Some concluding comments

· Commodity price spikes

Despite the currently depressed levels of most commodity prices, a sudden surge in commodity prices remains a real concern for many net food importing countries due to the cyclical nature of many commodity markets, the likely further draw-down of global stocks and the experience with surging import bills during the cereals price spike of 1995-96. Anticipating that trade liberalisation would create transitional problems for some food-importing developing countries in the form of higher food import bills, compensatory measures were envisaged under the Marrakesh Decision on Measures Concerning the Possible Negative Effects of the Reform Process on the Least-Developed and Net Food-Importing Developing Countries. The lack of response under the Decision during the 1995-96 price spike (in fact food aid declined during that period) has led many developing countries to call for more operationally effective, binding commitments in this area. FAO has recently contributed to the debate regarding options for making the Decision more effective, including modalities for a proposed revolving fund that would assist eligible countries during periods of surging food import bills.
· Depressed commodity prices
With the exception of the temporary price spike in 1995-96, most commodity prices have been at historically low levels in recent years, due primarily to market developments unrelated to the AoA. Depressed world prices - which are partly the result of the support and subsidy policies of OECD countries - create serious problems for farmers of developing countries who must compete in global markets and at home with these low-priced commodities. Since most developing countries now have only simple bound tariffs available to protect their farmers from import surges and/or a sudden fall in import prices, some form of easy-to-apply agricultural safeguard may be necessary for them. In the longer term, depressed commodity prices contribute to the under-investment in the agricultural sectors of developing countries. While consumers have benefited from these low prices, the long run sustainability of production under such conditions is jeopardised. Greater investment is needed to overcome supply-side constraints and to enhance the competitiveness and participation of developing countries in world markets.
· SPS and TBT measures
As traditional market access barriers are lowered, developing countries have expressed concern regarding the potential of SPS and TBT measures to restrict their exports. Their concern is two-fold: first that they lack the technical and financial capacity to fully participate in activities of international standard-setting bodies such as the Codex Alimentarius Commission (CAC) and the International Plant Protection Convention (IPPC), and second that they lack the supply-side capacity to meet the increasingly strict standards being adopted by the industrial countries. In response to both concerns, FAO has undertaken various initiatives to assist developing countries to build capacity and participate more actively in the work of both CAC and IPPC. More specifically, it has proposed the creation of a facility to help the world’s least developed countries improve the safety and quality of their food products. The proposal was made at the third UN Conference on the LDCs. Similar proposals are being considered to assist all developing countries.
· Intellectual property rights
Technical and financial assistance to developing countries is required in the field of IPRs, particularly as they relate to new varieties of plants and to promote access and transfer of technology, including biotechnology, in order to benefit from the obligations imposed by the TRIPS Agreement.

[5] The brief overview of the price trends over the past decade contained in this section uses FAO indices of representative international prices for groups of basic food commodities. The method of calculation of the indices and their exact commodity composition may be found on the FAO web site at the following URL: http://www.fao.org
[6] The growth rates were estimated using regression analysis and all the estimated growth rates except that for dairy products were statistically significant, reflecting the recent reversal in that market.
[7] An analysis was also conducted to determine whether there were any consistent changes in the intra-seasonal instability of prices of basic food commodities (as measured by the relevant FAO price indices) over the same period. The instability was measured by calculating coefficients (CV) of variability for each season using monthly data for each commodity group separately for the 1990-2001 period. Subsequently, these estimates (12 for each commodity group) were used in regression analysis to assess whether there was a significant trend in the values of the CVs through the period. A statistically significant increase in intra-seasonal instability was discovered only for oilseeds and meat, implying no statistically significant change in price instability of others.
[8] More detailed information about developments in China, especially with regard to the size of its stocks is available in the February 2001 issue of Food Outlook .
[9] Quarterly and monthly price data analysed are as follows: crude oil ($/barrel, f.o.b., Dubai); polypropylene ($/tonne, raffia grade, Western Europe); cotton ($/100lbs, 12 markets, US); jute ($/tonne, Chittagong-Chalna, Bangladesh); sisal ($/tonne, East African, London). The data used in the quarterly analysis run from 1977(Q1) to 2000(Q4) giving a total of 96 data points, while the monthly series runs from January 1980 to December 1999 giving a total of 240 data points. Sources of price data are as follows: crude oil and cotton from Financial Times; jute from Public Ledger; Sisal from Wigglesworth; polypropylene from Economic and Chemical News. All quantity data are from FAO. The price data are deflated when appropriate by the United States consumer price index, and the crude oil price is seasonally adjusted. The analysis uses the natural logarithms of the data.
[10] The tariffication formula was based on the gap between domestic and world reference prices during the 1986-88 base period: T=(Pw-Pd)/Pw * 100; where T is the ad valorem tariff equivalent and Pw and Pd are the world reference price and domestic price, respectively. It should be noted that a double tariff system was established for products subject to tariffication, whereby lower tariffs are applied to the specified in-quota volumes.
[11] AMAD is an inter-agency cooperative effort among Agriculture and Agri-Food Canada; EU Commission, DG Agriculture; OECD Directorate for Food, Agriculture and Fisheries; UNCTAD, TRAINS Database unit; USDA, Economic Research Service; and FAO, Commodities and Trade Division. The AMAD database is publicly accessible through the Internet at http://www.amad.net, and currently includes information on tariff protection and market access conditions for agricultural products in 16 developed countries (the 15 countries of the EU in one) and 30 developing countries.
[12] There is no standard definition of tariff peaks. Given the large price variations in agricultural products, 20 percent could be regarded as a low threshold; however, an earlier WTO/UNCTAD study used 12 percent as a threshold level. No account is taken of the possibility that a low bound tariff plus an associated special safeguard duty could also result in a higher tariff than the peak as defined here. See UNCTAD (2000).
[13] The differences between the results of the above mentioned studies and the results reported here can be explained by differences in the country groupings used, in the commodity grouping criteria employed and by the fact that the present analysis focuses only on tariff lines above the 20 percent level.
[14] Although the AoA gives some discretion to member countries to distribute the tariff cuts among different tariff lines (provided that a 15 percent (developed countries)/10 percent (developing countries) minimum cut is applied for each line), the analysis assumes that a 36 percent or a 24 percent linear cut would take place for each tariff line.
[15] Maize, millet and sorghum are internationally called coarse grains.
[16] Southern Africa has already entered the new marketing year, starting on 1 April 2001 and ending on 31 March 2002.
[17] Maize, sorghum and millet.
[18] The OECD Total Support Estimate is a broader concept than support to agriculture as measured by the WTO. The OECD concept includes distorting and non-distorting government transfers to agriculture (which correspond roughly to the Amber Box and Green Box supports as defined by the WTO) as well as the effects of border protection.
[19] Paragraph 2 of the Marrakesh Decision.
[20] The dispute successfully brought by India, Malaysia, Pakistan, Thailand and The Philippines against the United States on the import prohibition of certain shrimp and shrimp products was argued under the General Agreement, not the SPS or TBT Agreements.
[21] Examples: Australia's restriction on the import of durian (Thailand); Japan's restrictions on the import of sugarcane top and corncob (Indonesia); Mexico's prohibition of Thai milled rice (Thailand); - Australian restrictions on sauces containing benzoic acid (Philippines).

Previous Page Top of Page Next Page