Previous Page Table of Contents Next Page


3. ECONOMETRIC MODELS FOR CONSUMPTION ANALYSIS


Introduction

Application of the theory of the household requires a specific model. In general, econometric studies of demand include both single equations and systems of demand equations. The demand functions can be generalized for a consumer or a household buying n goods as:

qi = qi (p1, p2, ... pj, ... pn, I), i = 1, 2, ..., n.
(3.1)

where qi is the quantity demanded; p is the price, the subscript i denotes the commodities; and I is income. These "n equations" can be estimated by single equations or by systems of equations. In this study, Equation 3.1 is estimated in a budget share form. Extending the demand function for individual consumers to that for a group of consumers in most empirical applications requires the inclusion of demographic variables besides prices and income. In this section, the econometric models for 11 food items are described. The same methodology also applies to the model for seven meats.

Single equation model

The first empirical model applied in this study is the Working-Leser model. The original form of the Working-Leser model was discussed by Working (1943) and Leser (1963). Intriligator, Bodkin and Hsiao (1996) and Deaton and Muellbauer (1980a) provide a more detailed discussion of this functional form. In the Working-Leser model, each share of the food item is simply a linear function of the log of prices and of the total expenditure on all the food items under consideration. The Working-Leser food demand function can be expressed as:


(3.2)

where (i,j) represents the 11 food items; wi is the expenditure share of food i among the 11 food items; pj is the price of food j; and x is the total expenditure of all food items included in the model.

Hk includes dummy variables where k is 25:

ei's are random disturbances assumed with zero mean and constant variance. This model can be estimated for each food item by the ordinary least squares (OLS).

Demand elasticity formulae for Working-Leser model

It is easy to show the elasticity formulae for the Working-Leser model. The expenditure elasticity (ei) can be expressed as:

.
(3.3)

Taking a derivative of Equation 3.2 with respect to log(pj) yields, uncompensated own (j =i) and cross (j ¹i) price elasticities (eij) are as follows:


(3.4)

where is the Kronecker delta that is unity if i = j and zero otherwise. In this study, expenditure, own-price and cross-price elasticities are evaluated at sample means.

Income elasticity in the Working-Leser model

Since the Working-Leser model uses total expenditures for the group of food items included in the model, it does not provide a direct estimate of income elasticity. In order to estimate income elasticity, the following Engel function is estimated:


(3.5)

where x is total expenditures of the food included in the model; X is total expenditures of food and non-food consumer goods and services; P is Laspeyres price index for the eleven foods; and other demographic and dummy variables are the same as previously defined. Remaining variables are the same as those in Equation 3.2. Income elasticity can be estimated from Equations 3.2 and 3.5. From Equation 3.2, the expenditure elasticity, , can be estimated. From Equation 3.5, the responsiveness of expenditure on food items by income change, , can be derived. Hence, income elasticity is estimated as follows:

.
(3.6)

Tobit and Heckman's two-step estimator

When estimating income elasticities, the use of household-level microdata is a good way of avoiding the aggregation problem. However, the use of household microdata on detailed commodities is comlicated by the econometric problem, which arises when some households have zero consumption of one or more of the items considered. In the FIES, the zero consumption problem is particularly severe for rice, oil and fats and FAFH, among the 11 major food commodities, and for ground meat and bacon, in the seven meats model.

It is known that estimates of coefficients are inconsistent when only observed positive purchase data are used to estimate consumption behaviour by OLS regression. The dependent variables - the budget shares of the food items specified - are zero if a household does not purchase the food item, and positive if it does. Zero shares are censored by an unobservable latent variable. In this report, two different models have been applied to correct zero consumption: Heckman's two-step model and the standard Tobit estimator. The derivation of elasticity measure for each model is shown. Each model is based on different assumptions regarding zero consumption. Zero consumption is observed when no purchase of the particular item was made during the month-long survey period. If zero consumption is assumed to be due to sample selection, Heckman's two-step is the appropriate model. The Tobit model simply captures the corner solutions for utility maximization. The results from the three estimators, including OLS, are compared in the following subsections.

Tobit estimator and demand elasticities

The Tobit estimator and elasticity calculation have been the subject of many studies. Notation follows mainly Amemiya (1985) and Maddala (1983).

The Tobit estimator is defined as follows:


(3.7)

where b is a k × 1 vector of unknown parameters; si is a k × 1 vector of known variables; ui are residuals that are independently and normally distributed, with mean zero and a common variance s2; and y* is an unobservable latent variable.

McDonald and Moffitt (1980) describe how total change in y can be disaggregated into two parts: the change in y above the threshold, weighted by the probability of being above the threshold; and the change in the probability of being above the threshold, weighted by the expected value of y. Unconditional elasticity describes the elasticity of y from the mean of all observed values for y. Conditional elasticity is the elasticity measure that is conditional on the consumer's choice to purchase a non-zero quantity of the good.

Considering the model given in Equation 3.7 and the non-zero observations yi, the result is:


(3.8)

where fi and Fi are the density function and cumulative distribution function of the standard normal evaluated at . For notational convenience, z is defined as .

The following formula is used to obtain predicted values using all the observations:


(3.9)

Unconditional and conditional elasticities for a particular variable, s, in a general form can be obtained as follows:

Unconditional elasticity:


(3.10)

Conditional elasticity:


(3.11)

The prediction of yi, given si, can be obtained from the different expectation functions: unconditional and conditional expectations. Following Maddala (1983) and McDonald and Moffitt (1980), unconditional expectation can be obtained from the derivative of Equation 3.9 without the subscript i, which denotes observation:


(3.12)

From Equation 3.12, the partial derivative can be calculated as:


(3.13)

(See McDonald and Moffitt [1980] for the detailed derivation.)

From these general formulae for elasticity estimation, the elasticity formulae for the Leser-Working model can be derived. In this study, the Working-Leser Model is denoted as:


(3.14)

and

where subscript i denotes a good in question; X denotes total expenditure on 11 commodities; pi and qi denote price and quantity for ith commodity, respectively; and wi denotes the budget share of ith good, .

Expenditure elasticity is obtained in the following way:


(3.15)

Since the numerator of Equation 3.15 is the coefficient of Equation 3.14, this formula can be applied to Equation 3.14 evaluated at the sample mean such that f and F are the density function and cumulative density function, respectively, of the standard normal evaluated at zi. For convenience, Equation 3.14 can be rewritten in the compact form: .

Hence, unconditional expenditure elasticity is:


(3.16)

where the upper bar denotes the sample mean, and .

Conditional expenditure elasticity is:


(3.17)

Own-price elasticity becomes:


(3.18)

Unconditional own-price elasticity is:


(3.19)

Conditional own-price elasticity is:


(3.20)

In the same format, cross-price elasticity can be obtained as follows:


(3.21)

Unconditional cross-price elasticity is:


(3.22)

Conditional own-price elasticity is:


(3.23)

Heckman's two-step (sample selection) estimator

In order to correct for the sample bias problem in rice consumption, Heckman's two-step estimation (Heckit) procedure can be applied, as suggested by Heckman (1978). In the first stage, a probit regression is computed in order to estimate the probability that a given household consumes the food item in question. This regression is used to estimate the inverse Mills ratio (l) for each household, which is used as an instrument in the second regression. In the second stage, the initial Working-Leser model (Equation 3.2) with the inverse Mills ratio is estimated.

In the first stage, the household's decision is modelled as a dichotomous choice problem:


(3.24)

where Ii is one if a household consumes ith food item (i.e. wi > 0), and zero otherwise. Other variables have already been defined. From Equation 3.24, the inverse Mills ratio (l) for every household can be computed as:


(3.25)

where P, x, d are the vector of prices; expenditures and the vector of demographic variables for the household, respectively; fi is the density probability function; and Fi is the cumulative probability function. For notational convenience, this is set as:


(3.25')

where Gi is a vector of regressors explaining the binary choice in the first stage; and is the conformable parameter vector.

In the second step, the following Working-Leser demand function incorporating the computed inverse Mills ratio, , as an instrument variable is estimated:


(3.26)

where qi is the parameter associated with the inverse Mills ratio. It is important that only the non-zero observations on wi are used in the second-stage estimation in order to estimate the conditional elasticity.[6] The whole sample is used to estimate the unconditional elasticity.

It is important to note that at least one of the explanatory variables in the first equation is not included at the second step for identification, according to Maddala (1983) Amemiya (1985) and Johnston and DiNardo (1997). The city size dummy variables based on the population are added in the first step: cities are divided into major cities (population of at least 1 million), middle-sized cities (population of 150 000 to 1 million), small cities A (population of 50 000 to 150 000) and small cities B (population of fewer than 50 000).

Demand elasticities for Heckman's two-step estimator

Even though Heckman's two-step estimator is fairly common in empirical studies, there is little literature on its elasticity estimation. Byrne, Capps and Saha (1996) explicitly show elasticity estimates of Heckman's two-step estimator for a single equation case. Later, Saha, Capps and Byrne (1997) generalized the method from a single equation to a system of equations. For this report, the methodology developed by Byrne, Capps and Saha (1996) and Saha, Capps and Byrne (1997) was adapted and applied to the Working-Leser model.

At the first stage, the inverse Mills ratio is estimated by the dichotomous-choice probit model. In a general form, the estimated inverse Mills ratio, , is described in Equation 3.25. In the second stage equation, the conditional expectation of the dependent variable can be calculated in a general form as follows:

and

(3.27)

where is the vector of regressors explaining the magnitude of in the second stage equation; is the associated parameter vector; and is a parameter corresponding to the estimated inverse Mills ratio, which is estimated at the first stage. In order to derive conditional elasticity, only the non-zero observation of is used for the second stage of Heckman's two-step estimator.

Taking a partial derivative with respect to ( may be considered as any variable in the vector of regressors):


(3.28)

According to Saha, Cappas and Byrne (1997), this can be simplified as:


(3.29)

where and are parameters corresponding to and the inverse Mills ratio at the second stage equation, respectively; is a parameter associated with at the first stage; is the vector of regressors explaining the binary choice in the first stage; and is the comfortable parameter vector, as already defined. Marginal effects are evaluated at the sample mean. The average of the inverse Mills ratio can be estimated by adding up the results of all the observations and dividing by the number of observations.

In order to estimate unconditional elasticity, the whole sample needs to be used for the second stage so that zero-consumption households are taken into account. In the second stage estimation, the expectation of the dependent variables becomes as follows:


(3.30)


(3.31)

A partial derivative with respect to can be taken to produce the following:


(3.32)


(3.33)

Denoting as the proportion of observations for which , hence , Saha. Capps and Byrne (1997) suggest taking a weighted average of these two biases, as follows:


(3.34)

The sample mean for the bias term is calculated as before: the bias terms of each observation are added together and the result is divided by the number of observations.

In order to apply these computations for the Working-Leser model, the marginal value needs to be adjusted to follow the elasticity formula. It then becomes possible to calculate the elasticities for conditional price, conditional expenditure, unconditional price and unconditional expenditure, as follows:


(3.35)


(3.36)


(3.37)


(3.38)

A complete demand system

Deaton and Muellbauer (1980a; 1980b) developed a flexible demand system called the "almost ideal demand system" (AIDS). The concept of a flexible demand system is extremely useful for estimating a demand system with many desirable properties. As Moschini (1998) pointed out, the AIDS model automatically satisfies the aggregation restriction, and with simple parametric restrictions, homogeneity and symmetry can be imposed. In addition, the non-linear Engel curves of the AIDS model imply that an increase in income will lead to a decrease in the share of income allocated to a particular commodity, as well as a decrease in the income elasticity of that good when it is less than one. However, the AIDS model may be difficult to estimate because the price index is not linear in terms of parameters estimated. Owing to its simplicity, the linear approximate almost ideal demand system (LA/AIDS) is popular for empirical studies. Both the LA/AIDS and the AIDS models were applied for this report.

The AIDS model for the 11 food commodities can be estimated as follows:

i = 1, ..., 11
(3.41)

where wi is the budget share of good i; pj is the price of good j; x is the total expenditure of the goods in question; mi is the random disturbances assumed with zero mean and constant variance; and P is a translog price index defined by:


(3.42)

Where k is = 1, ..., 11; l is 1, ..., 11; and the gij parameters are defined under symmetry as follows:

j = 1, ..., 11
(3.43)

The model defined by Equations 3.41 to 3.43 is called the AIDS model.

It is easy to check that the adding-up restriction is satisfied with the given for all j:

, , and

(3.44)

The homogeneity restriction is satisfied for the AIDS model if, and only if, for all j:


(3.45)

The symmetry is satisfied by:


(3.46)

Using the price index in Equation 3.42 raises estimation difficulties caused by the non-linearity of parameters. In addition, the theory of the household does not provide any empirically plausible value for a0.

As Asche and Wessells (1997) point out, the Stone index is widely used for LA/AIDS estimation:

i = 1, ..., 11
(3.47)

where w is budget share among the 11 commodities. The Stone index is an approximation proportional to the translog, i.e. P = j P* where E(ln(j)) = a0. The LA/AIDS model with the Stone index can be denoted as follows:


(3.48)
where and .

Since prices will never be perfectly collinear, it is widely cited that applying the Stone index will introduce the units of measurement error (see Alston, Foster and Green, 1994; Asche and Wessells, 1997; Moschini, 1995). The Stone index does not satisfy the fundamental property of index numbers because it is variant to changes in the units of measurement for prices. One of the solutions to correct the units of measurement error is that prices are scaled by their sample mean. Following Moschini's suggestion (1995), a Laspeyres price index can be used to overcome the measurement error. Specifically, the log-linear analogue of the Laspeyres price index is obtained by replacing in Equation 3.47 with , which is a mean budget share. Hence, the Laspeyres price index becomes a geometrically weighted average of prices:


(3.49)

Substitution of Equation 3.49 into Equation 3.48 yields a LA/AIDS model with the Laspeyres price index as follows:


(3.50)

where .

Following Pollak and Wales (1978; 1981), linear demographic translating is applied, , where d and h are associated parameters and demographic variables, respectively. In this study, linear demographic translating replaces Equation 3.41 as follows:


(3.51)

where . The demographic and dummy variables used in the complete demand system are the same as the ones used in single equation models.

The adding-up restriction requires:

k = 1, ..., m
(3.52)

where m is the number of demographic and other dummy variables.

In order to correct for the zero consumption problem, the generalized Amemiya's two-stage estimators are applied to a simultaneous-equation model (see Amemiya, 1974; Lee and Pitt, 1986; and Heien and Wessells, 1990). In the first stage, the probit model with dichotomous choices is estimated. The inverse Mills ratio is derived from the regression results. For the LA/AIDS model, the inverse Mills ratios of only rice, fats and oil and FAFH are used. These three inverse Mills ratios are used as instruments in the second stage. Similar arguments are adopted from the Heckman's two-step estimator, as already discussed.

Demand elasticities for the AIDS model

The elasticity derivations for the AIDS and LA/AIDS models are widely investigated and well documented. Following Buse (1994) and Green and Alston (1990), taking the derivative of Equation 3.48 with respect to ln(x), the expenditure elasticity ei can be obtained as follows:


(3.53)

Taking the derivative with respect to ln(pj), uncompensated own- (j =i) and cross- (j ¹i) price elasticities, , become as follows:


(3.54)

where is the Kronecker delta that is unity if i = j, and zero otherwise. In this study, the sample mean is used for the point of normalization.

The Hicksian compensated price elasticities can be derived for the AIDS and LA/AIDS models. The compensated price elasticities, , at the point of normalization become as follows:


(3.55)

For the AIDS model, following Buse (1994), Equation 3.53 is applied for expenditure elasticity. Following Green and Alston (1990), uncompensated own- and cross-price elasticities, , become as follows:

.
(3.56)

Compensated own- and cross-price elasticities, , become as follows:

.
(3.57)


[5] Only ten monthly dummies are included in the model because CPI data for FAFH are obtained on a monthly basis.
[6] When a system of equations with inverse Mills ratio is used, the convention is to use the whole sample.

Previous Page Top of Page Next Page